People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 52 December 29, 2013 |
Prabhat
Patnaik TWO alternative
perspectives on the appropriate
trajectory of economic development, almost diametrically
opposed to one
another, are in contention in As against this,
the other perspective suggests
that the pursuit of growth by providing “incentives” to the
corporates, will
not improve the lot of the poor either through any automatic
“trickle down” or
through the eventual availability of larger fiscal resources
to the government
for expenditure on the poor (since such resources will
always be required for
providing “incentives” to the corporates). Hence waiting for
poverty
eradication to occur spontaneously as a consequence of
growth amounts to
waiting forever. The governments must therefore follow a
redistributive agenda immediately.
And if it is pursued, then growth, of a different kind,
catering to the
demands created through such redistribution, will
occur which will be more
“inclusive”, more sustainable and no less rapid. The difference
between these two perspectives is
often labelled mistakenly as “growth versus
redistribution” or as “a
single-minded pursuit of growth versus a lackadaisical
pursuit of growth”. The
real difference however does not lie in these: it lies
essentially in two
alternative strategies of effecting growth, one
emphasizing incentives to
corporates; and the other eschewing such incentives and
emphasizing instead the
need for income redistribution as a means of promoting
growth. Portraying
this difference as a “growth versus redistribution” issue
tends to hide the
real difference, which relates to a “pro-corporate
redistribution for effecting
growth” versus a “pro-poor redistribution for effecting
growth”. I shall
therefore refer to these strategies as “pro-corporate” and
“redistributive”
growth strategies respectively (since the bald term
“redistributive” in common
parlance refers usually to “redistributive towards the
poor”). While these two
perspectives, which can also be
seen alternatively as emphasizing the supply-side and the
demand side
respectively, have been much debated theoretically, the
empirical debate has
tended to pick up prototypes of each strategy and to compare
them. And in this
context, two particular states in The fact that
Gujarat does represent the
pro-corporate strategy is underscored by
the strong corporate backing that is being provided at
present to the Gujarat
chief minister in his bid to emerge as the new prime
minister, including the
credence given by the corporate media to his Party’s claim
that he is the man
for “development”. And neo-liberal economists who are
necessarily committed to
a pro-corporate strategy are working overtime to show that DISREGARD FOR EVIDENCE What is surprising
about this campaign however
is its disregard for evidence. In fact, the evidence shows
not only that
Gujarat lags woefully behind Kerala and many other states in
terms of social
indicators, and even in terms of the rate of improvement of
social indicators, but
also that the growth rate of its real per capita gross
state domestic product
has not been significantly different from Kerala’s, and
has been less than that
of some other, larger, states. Of course gross
state domestic product data are
both weak for each state and not easily comparable across
states. But since an
issue has been made of it by neo-liberal economists, let us
use whatever data
we have. Table 1 gives the average annual compound growth
rates of per capita
real GSDP at factor cost (at 2004-5 prices) for the
seven-year period 2004-5 to
2011-12 for Gujarat, Kerala, and a few other states (chosen
entirely for
illustrative purposes). The choice of 2004-5 as the initial
year is dictated
both by the availability of a series with base prices of
that date and by the
fact that the recent growth acceleration of the Indian
economy began around
then; and the choice of 2011-12 as the end point is because
Gujarat data in the
cited source are available only until then. Table 1: Growth
Rates of Per
Capita GSDP (at 2004-5 prices): 2004-5 to
2011-12 Tamilnadu:
8.65
percent Kerala :
7.91
percent Andhra Pradesh:
7.6
percent All Source: The GSDP
data are from the Planning
Commission. The population of each state is assumed to grow
at the same rate as
the observed annual compound growth rate for the period
between the two census
years 2001 and 2011. While the
difference between Gujarat’s and
Kerala’s GSDP growth rates is marginal, notwithstanding the
fact that Kerala,
unlike Gujarat, maintains extraordinarily high levels of
public social
expenditure to keep up its welfare orientation, the case of
Tamilnadu is
instructive. Tamilnadu of late has been pursuing a
redistributive, social
expenditure-augmenting strategy that has already yielded
significant results in
terms of closing its gap in social indicators vis-à-vis
Kerala. The fact that
it has nonetheless exceeded
II Even during this
period however But changes in There
is little scope, alas, for consoling oneself in this manner,
because in terms
of satisfying the most elemental human need of its people,
namely hunger, which
does not figure in the HDI, This is also borne
out by the data on the per
capita intake of calories. Table 2 provides these data and
also shows that the
decline in per capita calorie intake between the two
end-points has been
accompanied a decline in per capita protein intake. Table 2: Per
Capita Daily Calorie and Protein
Intake in Calories Protein Rural Urban Rural Urban 1983 2113 2000 1993-4
1994 2027 55.6 54.9 2004-5 1923 1991 53.3 57.3 2009-10 1982 1983 54.0 53.3 Source:
National Sample Survey What is striking
about these figures is not only
the decline between the end-points, but also the fact that unlike
in the
rest of India the calorie intake in rural areas of Gujarat
is lower than in its
urban areas after 1983. It is a well-known fact that
since rural labour
typically requires greater energy expenditure the calorie
intake needs to be
greater in rural areas, and this is invariably the pattern
actually observed.
The fact that Gujarat constitutes an exception to this
established pattern
suggests that purchasing power in rural Gujarat, which has a
substantial tribal
population, is simply too meager to permit a higher intake
of calories. INADEQUACY OF PURCHASING POWER The decline in
calorie intake over time is often
attributed to changing tastes or to dietary diversification.
But all over the
world, taking all kinds of consumption into account
(including of processed
foods), the total per capita calorie intake rises with per
capita income, both
cross-sectionally and over time. If the per capita intake
has been coming down,
then since the rich would not be reducing their calorie
intake (even if they
diversified their diets this is unlikely to happen), it
follows that the
calorie intake of the poor must be getting squeezed even
harder than these
figures suggest, and the only reason for it would be the
inadequacy of
purchasing power in their hands relative to food prices. The
conclusion is
inescapable therefore that notwithstanding Gujarat’s
performance in terms of
the growth of its GSDP, there has been an increase in the
relative magnitude of
absolute hunger in the state; and this has been because of
the inadequacy of
purchasing power in the hands of the working people.
III This fact should
come as no surprise. GSDP
growth can make an impact on the conditions of the people in
either one or both
of two possible ways. One, if it uses up labour reserves, in
which case those
who are underemployed get fuller
employment and therefore increase their earnings, and
those who were not
underemployed but were employed to start with, get higher
wages on account of
the tightness of the labour market. Two, GSDP growth can
make more fiscal
resources available for transfers to the poor which can
improve the conditions
of the people. This second avenue
however gets foreclosed
because the argument for enlarging GSDP by giving
concessions to corporate
interests does not have any determinate temporal limits to
it. If the
proponents of such a pro-corporate strategy were to set down
some specific
limit, such that until that limit is reached GSDP growth is
to be encouraged by
giving incentives to the rich, but once it is reached
redistribution towards
the poor is to commence, then there would be some scope left
for redistribution
towards the poor. But since no such break, no such
threshold, is ever
prescribed, no shift in strategy in the form of a change in
the direction of
income distribution is ever contemplated. This second avenue
therefore is a
non-starter. Just to give one
example, the Gujarat government
allegedly offered the Tatas a sum of Rs 31,000 crores under
various kinds of
subsidies to induce them to shift their Nano plant to Now, as regards the
first avenue, namely the
using up of labour reserves, whether it happens or not
depends on the rates of
growth of labour demand and labour supply. If the net rate
of growth of labour
demand, after taking into account the displacement of the
working population
owing to the unviability of certain activities (for instance
petty producers
getting displaced by competition, or by encroachment through
land appropriation,
from the corporate sector), exceeds the rate of growth of
labour supply,
consisting of the natural growth of the work-force owing to
population
increase, and the immigration into the region, then the
existing labour
reserves will get progressively used up; in the opposite
case they will keep
increasing in absolute and relative terms. The problem with
the “pro-corporate”
growth strategy however is that its capacity to generate net
labour demand is
exceedingly limited, well below the rate of growth of labour
supply. And this
has been the case in This can be clearly
established as follows. The
National Sample Survey uses a number of different concepts
of employment, an
important one of which is “usual principal status”. This is
computed by taking
note of what people themselves declare to be their principal
activity during
the reference period on a usual basis, and refers therefore
to a state of being
employed in a relatively stable sense. Now, it stands to
reason that in a
situation of tightness in the labour market, the proportion
of “usual principal
status” employment to the total employment, and hence to the
total labour
supply, should increase, since employers would not risk
being without enough
workers and would offer employment on a more stable basis;
and the opposite
should happen when the labour market is slackening. Hence an
indication of
whether the relative size of the labour reserves to the
total labour supply is
decreasing or increasing may be obtained by comparing the
rate of growth of
“usual principal status” employment with that of labour
supply. Taking India as a
whole, between 2004-5 and
2009-10, the rate of growth of “usual principal status”
employment for those in
the 15-59 age group was a meagre 0.88 percent per annum
according to the
National Sample Survey (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2011), even
though the rate of
growth of GDP at factor cost (at 2004-5 prices) was 8.73
percent per annum.
Since Gujarat pursued the same neo-liberal “pro-corporate”
growth strategy that
was being generally pursued in the country as a whole, but
in a far more
concentrated form, the rate of growth of employment in This rate which is
not likely to have been
exceeded throughout Gujarat’s recent growth phase, is far
short of the rate of
growth of the population of Gujarat during 2001-11, and
hence of the natural
rate of growth of the work-force, even if we do not take
into account the
substantial influx of migrant labour into the state. Far
from getting
exhausted, labour reserves in As a matter of fact
during this period
agriculture and industry have registered negative growth in
employment (Rani and
Kalaiyarasan 2013). Whatever employment growth has occurred
has been in the
service sector and taken the form of self-employment and
causal employment,
indicative of an increase in “informalisation”, and a
decline in the quality of
employment, suggestive of a slackening of the labour market
and an increase in
the relative size of the labour reserves. Not surprisingly
this has had its
impact on the wage rate as well: in 2007-8 among regular
workers, Gujarat’s
wage rate was lower than the average all-India level for
every category of
workers, rural male, rural female, urban male and urban
female. Its rank
among the 20 major states for each of these categories was
17, 9, 18 and 13
respectively (Hirway and Shah, 2011). Time-series data
for casual workers show a
decline in its rank, in terms of the level of the wage rate
among the 20 major
states, between 1999-2000 and 2007-8, from 9 to 14 in the
case rural male
workers and also from 9 to 14 in the case of urban female
workers. In the case
of rural female workers’ wages and those of urban males, its
rank remains
unchanged at 8 between these two dates. The nominal daily
wage rate of rural males, the
largest of these categories, when deflated by the official
consumer price index
of rural labourers, shows an annual compound rate of growth
of real wages in
Gujarat of only 2 percent between these dates, while the
rate for The redistributive
growth trajectory by
contrast, precisely because it puts directly or indirectly
more purchasing
power in the hands of the working people, generates demand
for a range of
simple goods whose production is both employment intensive,
and not
particularly subject to labour saving technical progress. It
therefore
generates greater employment growth and thereby sets up a
virtuous cycle that
can lead to an exhaustion of labour reserves, which
constitutes a necessary
condition for poverty removal. But since it moves away from
neo-liberalism, it
entails a degree of delinking from the global economy. The “pro-corporate”
growth strategy pursued in
the neo-liberal era in the country has not only exacerbated
income and wealth
inequalities, but has intensified the magnitude of hunger
even in the midst of
high rates of GDP growth.
REFERENCES Chandrasekhar C.P.
and Ghosh J. (2011) “The
Latest Employment Trends from the NSS”, The Hindu
Business Line, July
12. Patnaik P. (2013)
“A Critique of the Welfare
Theoretic Basis of the Measurement of Poverty”, Economic
and Political
Weekly, April 6. Rani R. and
Kalaiyarasan A. (2013) “Galloping
Growth Stagnant Employment: Mapping Regional and Social
Differences” in Atul
Sood ed. Poverty Amidst Prosperity: Essays on the
Trajectory of Development
in Gujarat, Aakar Books,