People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 44 November 03, 2013 |
Capitalism
and the Value of Money Prabhat
Patnaik CAPITALISM is
pre-eminently a money-using
system. Commodity exchange in this system is necessarily
mediated by money:
between the sale of a commodity and the purchase of other
commodities from the
proceeds of this sale, these proceeds must be held for a
greater or lesser
length of time in the form of money. A certain proportion of
their wealth, it
follows, is always held by individual wealth-owners under
capitalism in the
form of money. Contracts for payments in the future are made
in terms of money.
All these become possible because of a pervasive general
belief that the value
of money in terms of the world of commodities is unlikely to
experience any
drastic decline. Lenin was aware of
the dangers to capitalism
posed by a decline in the value of money vis a vis the world
of commodities.
John Maynard Keynes in his famous book,
The Economic Consequences of the Peace, published in
1919, had this to say
about Lenin: “Lenin is said to have declared that the best
way to destroy the
Capitalist System is to debauch the currency..As the
inflation proceeds..all
permanent relations between debtors and creditors which form
the ultimate
foundation of capitalism, become so utterly disordered as to
be almost
meaningless..Lenin was certainly right. There is no subtler,
no surer means of
overturning the existing basis of society than to debauch
the currency.” The necessity to
prevent such a debauchment of
the currency increases as the volume of financial assets
increases relative to
that of produced commodities. Any decline in the value of
money vis a vis
commodities, entails, other things being the same, a decline
in the value of
financial assets as well, since their money value is
independently determined
and is not indexed to the prices of commodities. What some
economists call
“financialisation”, ie, the enormous growth in the size of
the financial sector
in modern capitalism, increases a myriad-fold the need to
ensure that the value
of money remains stable, so that the command over resources
represented by
financial assets does not diminish. Since the
preservation of the value of money is
so important for capitalism, how is it actually achieved?
The first and the
most obvious means of doing so is the reserve army of
labour. The reserve army
is usually seen only as a means of restricting the real wages so that the process of
appropriation of surplus value
remains unimpaired. But the reserve army does not affect
only the real wages;
it plays the role above all of ensuring that the money wage claims of workers remain
restricted. If the reserve army
of labour becomes too small, ie, the unemployment rate falls
below a certain
level, then money wages and prices in the capitalist economy
would shoot
upwards. Joan Robinson the renowned But the perennial
maintenance of a reserve army
of labour is only one of the means for preserving the value
of money. Such
preservation also requires that there should be no
inflationary pressures
arising from a rise in the prices of the primary commodities
which are produced
in distant lands often by pre-capitalist producers and then
imported into the
capitalist metropolis. The prices of these commodities in
terms of the currency
of the capitalist metropolis must also not increase. This latter was
historically ensured through
colonialism. Even after the end of formal colonialism it is
ensured by a range
of new devices, all of which constitute the architecture of
imperialism More
generally therefore one can say that one of the functions of
imperialism, both
in the past and now, is to ensure this stability in the
value of money. ROLE OF IMPERIALISM
Since the first of
these mechanisms, viz, the
maintenance of a reserve army of labour is quite well
understood, let us
concentrate on the second mechanism, ie, the role of
imperialism (used in a more
inclusive sense than Lenin had done). And here there are two
distinct issues.
The first is that the money incomes of the producers of
these commodities, the
peasants and petty producers in the “outlying regions”, must
not be allowed to
increase; and this is ensured through the fact that they are
themselves
situated within a vast “reserve army” ( a second reserve
army as it were)
located in these “outlying regions” and created though the
colonial processes
of “drain of wealth” and “deindustrialisation”. These processes
created mass unemployment which
never got eliminated through absorption into the capitalist
sector, either in
the metropolis (to which in any case the third world
unemployed could not
migrate at will owing to restrictions on migration that
exist to this day), or
in the third world itself. There is therefore a permanent
pool of unemployed,
underemployed, semi-employed, informally employed, and
disguised-unemployed
persons in the third world, which ensures that the
bargaining power of the third
world petty producers is never strong enough to impart an
autonomous upward
push to their money earnings. Usually it is only
the reserve army of labour
existing in the metropolis itself that is recognised as
such. The existence of
the vast unemployed and underemployed mass that also acts as
a labour reserve
for capitalism, restricting the real wages and money wages
not only of workers
in their immediate proximity in the third world, but even of
workers in the
metropolis itself in a situation (as now) of free flow of
goods and capital
across borders, and also keeping down the money earnings of
the petty producers
who sell primary commodities to the metropolis, is often not
recognised as
such. Metropolitan
capitalism in fact has not only a
local labour reserve but also a distant labour reserve,
which, even when it
exists as labour reserve, plays the role of keeping all
workers, and primary
commodity suppliers, in check, and which can be called upon
periodically to
even provide actual labour supply to the metropolis when
needed, as in the
post-war period. These local and distant labour reserves
therefore have the
important function of ensuring stability in the value of
money in the
capitalist metropolis. INCOME DEFLATION
Let us now move to
the second issue. And this
concerns the fact that as accumulation occurs, the demand
for such commodities
produced in the “outlying regions” increases; and if their
prices are not to
increase, for that again would jeopardize the value of
money, then their
supplies must keep increasing. But many of these
commodities, for instance
those produced from the tropical land mass, are such that
their supplies cannot
be augmented easily. The magnitude of the tropical land mass
is given and
cannot be augmented; unless substantial steps are taken to
bring in multiple
cropping, or to raise the land yield through technological
progress, the output
of commodities produced on this land mass simply cannot be
augmented. These steps however
require State effort; and
apart from a brief period after decolonisation when the dirigiste regimes in the third world
undertook such effort, through
public investment in irrigation, through research carried
out in government
institutions to develop high-yielding seed varieties,
through erecting a massive
network of extension services, through making inputs
including institutional
credit cheaply available to the peasantry, and through
offering assured
remunerative prices, this effort has been conspicuous by its
absence. Under
these circumstances, supplies of these commodities to meet
the requirement of
the capitalist metropolis have been ensured
by squeezing their absorption within the “outlying
regions” themselves. This was blatantly
done during the colonial
period. Indeed the “drain” and “deindustrialisation” had the
effect of reducing
local purchasing power and hence local absorption of a
variety of goods which
then became available to the metropolis without any increase
in their prices.
And even if these were not the goods directly required by
the metropolis, the
land that was devoted to their production within the third
world, could now be
switched to the production of those goods which were
demanded within the
metropolis. We thus had a system of absolute impoverishment
of the third world
population to make goods available to the metropolis without
any increase in
their prices and hence without any threat to the value of
money or any
prospects of “debauchment” of currency. In the more recent
period, the neo-liberal
dispensation, by restricting government expenditure through
“austerity”, which
also squeezes purchasing power in the hands of the people;
by cutting down on
subsidies directed to the petty producers and the people at
large; by privatising
essential services and hence making them more expensive;
restrict the
absorption of goods by the domestic population, which in
turn makes possible
larger supplies of such goods, or of others that compete for
the same land
mass, to the metropolis. Notwithstanding all
these measures of “income
deflation” imposed on the people in the third world
economies, however, these
supplies sometimes may still be insufficient for the needs
of the metropolis,
in which case their prices rise relative to the money
incomes of buyers within
the third world economy itself, and supplies are released by
what economists
call “forced saving” by the third world buyers. They are
forced in other words
to absorb less, not because their money incomes are squeezed
but because the
prices they have to pay increase relative to their money
incomes. Such increase in
prices of commodities however
is not allowed to affect the metropolitan economy and the
stability of the
value of its currency, because the
exchange rate in the third world goes down in tandem with
the rise in prices,
so that the dollar prices of such commodities do not
increase. This does
not even require any specific intervention: if there is
inflation, then wealth
holders expect the exchange rate to depreciate and they
speculate against the
third world currency, so that the exchange rate actually
depreciates. Capitalism in short
has a whole array of
measures in place to ensure that there is no debauchment of
its currency. But
an important fall-out of it, not often recognised, is that
significant segments
of the world’s population get absolutely impoverished in the
process. Marx’s
insight that the capitalist system creates wealth at pole
and poverty at
another is as true today as it ever was.