People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 43 October 27, 2013 |
Changes
Being Mooted in the Banking Sector
Prabhat
Patnaik
NEW banking licenses
are to be issued to the
private sector post-haste before January 2014. This is the
third occasion,
after 1994 and 2001, when such licenses are to be given. But
this time, unlike
on the two earlier occasions when the Reserve Bank of
This threatens to
take us back to the days
before bank nationalisation in 1969, when all big houses had
their own in-house
banks. Indeed all the big banks at the time were owned by
corporate houses
which mobilised deposits from the public for promoting the
interests of their
respective groups. Banking meant furthering the group’s
strategy; credit went
where the group’s interest demanded; and sectors like
agriculture where peasant
production dominated and the corporate groups had little
interest at that time,
were cut off from institutional credit.
FUNDAMENTAL
SOCIAL
SIGNIFICANCE
Bank nationalisation
was meant to change all
that. It was based on a simple premise, namely that banking
was different from
other activities, that the “credit market” differed from other
“markets”. In
other markets, like say the furniture market, commodities are
sold against
pre-existing resources in the pockets of the buyers: sellers
exchange C for M
and buyers exchange M for C. In the credit “market” however
new resources (or
command over resources) are put into the pockets of the
customers: fresh M is
created by the banks which give it to borrowers against only
IOUs. What the
banks give out is command over capital; whom they give such
command to
determines the entire trajectory of development. What banks do
is therefore of
fundamental social
significance,
since it determines whether growth occurs at all, which
sectors grow, which
groups grow and which regions grow. And if what banks do is of
such fundamental
social significance, then society must have control over what
banks do. This
was the logic of bank nationalisation which was carried out
after a brief
period of futile attempt at what was called “social control
over banks”.
This logic remains as
valid today as it ever
was. The neo-liberal argument which has surfaced since then
does not, indeed it
cannot, contest the fact that society has priorities which
banks must serve.
What it says is that banks can serve these priorities if left
to their own
devices, ie, if the credit “market” is left free, subject to
obeying certain
overall parameters of monetary policy.
This argument however
is erroneous for two
obvious reasons. First, freeing the credit “market” can never
bring adequate
institutional credit to peasants and petty producers, in which
case either the
sectors where they are located must languish, to the detriment
of society; or
they will perforce be replaced by corporate capital, causing
acute mass
distress, which again no society can tolerate. Second, the
market, as John
Maynard Keynes had pointed out long ago, is intrinsically
incapable of
differentiating between “speculation” and “enterprise”. Hence
in a free market
not only does “speculation” thrive at the expense of
“enterprise”, but this
fact brings periodic mass ruin to the wealth-holders
themselves. Since we have
just seen an example of such mass ruin in the 2008 financial
crisis, from which
banks had to be bailed out by the provision of as much as $ 13
trillion from
the public exchequer in the
There is in short no
alternative to social
control over banks if social goals are to be achieved and the
only effective
way of exercising such control is through public ownership of
banks. If private
ownership of the means of production in general is inimical to
social good,
then private ownership of banks is quintessentially so.
But the persistent
demand of international
finance capital has been for privatising publicly-owned banks
in
Another pointer in
the same direction is the
invitation by RBI governor Raghuram Rajan to foreign banks to
operate in
This has an immediate
implication that must be
noted. Bank nationalisation had brought institutional credit
to sectors of
petty production neglected until then, and above all to
peasant agriculture. Of
course, the distribution of such credit had been unequal
across the peasantry;
it is the rich peasants and the landlords who had been the
biggest
beneficiaries of institutional credit. Nonetheless the Green
Revolution would
have been impossible without the disbursement of institutional
credit on the
scale that bank nationalisation ensured. Notwithstanding
inequalities in credit
disbursement within agriculture, the constraint that the
stagnation of this
sector had imposed on the development of the Indian economy,
which became
manifest in the mid-sixties food crisis (and the Bihar famine)
and which made
India dependent upon imperialism for food imports, could be
overcome through
increased institutional credit to agriculture. True, several
measures acted
conjointly towards improving
After economic
“liberalisation”, institutional
credit to agriculture, as is well-known, has dried up
significantly. Priority
sector norms remain; but not only are they flouted, but even
the definition of
“priority sector” has been so expanded that genuine credit to
agriculture has
become a meagre component of it. The foreign banks flout even
these norms with
impunity; and private sector banks follow them closely. Public
sector banks,
notwithstanding all the above caveats, are still the best
performers in
priority sector lending.
Enlarging the
presence of foreign banks and
corporate house banks at this juncture therefore is quite
bizarre. The
government has just enacted a Food Security legislation
covering over
two-thirds of the country’s population. If such a large
segment of the
population is to increase its food intake, then obviously
there has to be an
increase in food output in the country. Such an increase is
inconceivable
without a substantial increase in institutional credit to
peasant agriculture.
This needs a strict definition of priority sector lending, a
firm directive to
public sector banks to adhere to priority sector lending
norms, and penalisation
of those banks, especially foreign and private banks, which
have systematically
defaulted on priority sector lending even on its current loose
definition. The
fact that instead of doing this the government is actually
encouraging the
growth of precisely that sector within banking that does not
care about
priority sector lending, shows its lack of seriousness in
implementing its own
Food Security legislation. Quite obviously foreign banks for
whom the red
carpet is being unrolled, cannot be shown the door for not
meeting priority
sector lending norms once they have entered the country.
The changes being
mooted in the banking sector
in other words are so flagrantly in contradiction with what
the Food Security
legislation demands that one cannot help feeling that once the
elections are
over this legislation will be given a quiet burial. Already
the legislation
incorporates the possibility of cash payment in lieu of food;
so, once the
elections are over, the government will quietly shift to cash
payments, and,
with prices rising as at present, the real value of the cash
transfers will be
allowed to get eroded over time, quietly undermining this
much-hyped measure
which the neo-liberal wing of the government has been in any
case coerced into
accepting.
Another development
points in the same
direction. The government is making budgetary
resources available to public sector banks on the basis
of which they can
give loans to make the purchase of private vehicles easier.
This is supposed to
be a measure to boost industrial demand in the economy and
counter the slowdown
that has occurred.
CLASS
BIAS
There are however two
ways of boosting demand.
One is via consumer credit. The other is via giving loans to
producers in
sectors such as agriculture, whose output, and hence demand
for industrial
goods, can thereby be boosted. The latter has the obvious
“advantage” that even
while boosting industrial demand, it adds to the nation’s food
output and the
purchasing power of large numbers of peasants and agricultural
labourers. The
fact that instead of following this latter course for
expanding the home
market, the government has followed the former, which is
nothing else but the
path followed by the American banks that created a credit
bubble only for it to
burst later to the detriment of the country’s financial
system, is indicative
of the utter class bias of the Manmohan Singh government.
Giving easy credit
for the purchase of vehicles is a direct boost to the markets
and hence profits
of the corporate sector that is engaged in producing such
vehicles, while
enlarging the domestic market via an expansion of agricultural
output and the
purchasing power of the masses is too roundabout a route for
corporate capital.
These new directions
in banking policy that
privilege consumer credit over producer credit, that privilege
the
corporate-financial elite over peasant agriculture, that roll
back the thrust
of bank nationalisation and expose the economy to financial
crises have got to
be resisted with vigour in the interests of the nation.