People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 40 October 06, 2013 |
TWO
COURSES
Prabhat
Patnaik
THE fact that the
precipitous fall in the rupee has been halted and even
slightly reversed in the
last few days has created an impression that
The announcement
by the chairman of the Federal Reserve Board of the US, Ben
Bernanke, that the
Fed will continue for some more time with its policy of
“quantitative easing”,
i.e. of buying bonds and pumping money into the economy, has
led to an easier
flow of finance to the “newly emerging markets” than had been
the case earlier
after Bernanke had announced that “quantitative easing” would
come to an end.
So the stock market and the rupee have looked up.
But this temporary
reprieve for the rupee should not obscure the fact that the
basic problem,
namely of a current account deficit that is way above what the
country can
expect to finance on a sustained basis through capital
inflows, has not gone
away. Indeed the latest figures show that in the first
quarter, April-June, of
2013-14, the current account deficit was 4.9 per cent of the
GDP which far
exceeds the 2.5 per cent that the government itself considers
sustainable on
the basis of capital inflows.
As long as this
basic problem of an unsustainable current account deficit is
there,
notwithstanding occasional reprieves like now, the secular
trend for the rupee
will be downwards which will also mean a perpetuation of
cost-push inflation,
with rising rupee prices of imported goods like oil being
passed on to the people
at large.
OUTCOME
OF
IMPORT
SURGE
There are two
alternative explanations of this basic problem, from which two
sharply
divergent conclusions follow about what is to be done. The
first explanation
which is common to the neo-liberal perspective is as follows:
the large current
account deficit is because of excess demand in the economy,
i.e. because the
overall magnitude of demand in the economy exceeds what the
country can
produce; this excess demand arises largely because of the
excess demand of the
government sector which is reflected in its large fiscal
deficit; the economy
therefore should attempt in the short-run
to finance the current account deficit as best as it can, by
attracting
adequate foreign resources, for which it has to “open up” more
to foreign
capital; in the long
run however it
has to reduce this deficit by curtailing the fiscal deficit.
The panacea in
short is to “liberalise” as much as possible even while
imposing austerity on
the government.
The problem with
this reading is that its very premise is wrong: the large
current account
deficit is not because
the economy’s
demand for goods exceeds what it can produce. On the
contrary, its
productive capacity is lying unutilised in a number of
sectors. The large
current account deficit is because of an import surge at the expense of domestic production made
possible by the
neo-liberal policy of import liberalisation, which has
occurred even while
exports continue to be sluggish owing to the global capitalist
crisis. In other
words domestic unutilised capacity has been caused by the same
factor which has
caused the large current account deficit, namely the import
surge made possible
by liberalisation.
This import surge
is not confined only to gold and petro-products. It has
occurred in a large
number of spheres, and the gold import itself, far from being
a cause of the
crisis is more a response to it (which no doubt aggravates the
crisis at the
same time): wealth-holders worried about the prospects of a
depreciating rupee,
both vis-a-vis foreign currencies like the US dollar and
vis-à-vis the world of
commodities in general (owing to inflation), wish to hold gold
as an asset
which explains the increases in its imports.
CURE
WORSE
THAN
THE DISEASE
If the neo-liberal
panacea, whose basic premise is wrong, is tried out, then far
from alleviating
the crisis, it will only aggravate it further, while at the
same time worsening
the condition of the people. A curtailment of the fiscal
deficit typically
takes the form of reducing development expenditure in rural
areas, welfare
expenditure and subsidies for the poor. Such reduction has a
direct adverse
effect upon their living standards. At the same time however,
since the import
content of such expenditure is minuscule, its curtailment does
not reduce the
current account deficit; what it does instead is to reduce the
demand for a
range of domestically produced goods, which further worsens
domestic recession
and unemployment.
Take a simple
example. Suppose Rs 100 was being handed over to the poor in
the form of a
subsidy. It would be getting spent on some simple
locally-produced goods with
very little import content. If this subsidy is cut, then the
condition of the
poor worsens directly; the local demand generated by it gets
curtailed, causing
a reduction in domestic production and employment (which
further worsens the
condition of the poor); at the same time however there is not
an iota of
improvement in the current account deficit.
Hence, if we
follow such a course of action, then the ongoing crisis
emanating from the
unsustainable current account deficit will continue as before;
but it will be
further compounded by an additional dose of recession and
unemployment caused
by the government’s resort to austerity, while making the
people worse off,
both because of the austerity and because of the additional
dose of
unemployment.
But that is not
all. The greater “opening up” to foreign capital which is
resorted to for
financing the current account deficit, also has a two-fold
effect. On the one
hand it entails the displacement of local production by
foreign capital, which
raises imports and reduces domestic employment. The classic
example here is the
entry of retail giants like Walmart, who not only displace
large numbers of
petty traders, but also additionally displace other local
producers because
they import their wares from the cheapest global sources,
which means from
third world producers even more hapless than those in India.
Increased
unemployment is thus caused along with larger imports and
hence a worsening of
the current account deficit.
On the other hand
however the economy becomes even more vulnerable to capital
outflows with every
such “opening up” to foreign capital. Naturally, the greater
the magnitude of
foreign capital operating in the economy, the wider the area
over which it
holds sway, the greater the potential outflow in the event of
a loss of
“confidence” in the economy or in the value of the rupee.
Hence if the panacea
for the long-term problem of an unsustainable current account
deficit in the
form of a curtailment of the fiscal deficit, is
counterproductive, then
the measures for
meeting the short-term
problem of financing this deficit within the neo-liberal
regime by attracting
foreign capital, are no less so. Attracting foreign capital,
quite apart from
its other effects in terms of causing unemployment by
displacing domestic
producers, is a double-edged weapon: it may help the balance
of payments
immediately by financing the current deficit, but by the same
token it makes
the balance of payments more vulnerable over time.
All this should
come as no surprise. The world economy continues to be in a
crisis. The very
announcement by Ben Bernanke that the Fed will continue with
“quantitative
easing” for a longer period, which has brought some immediate
relief to the
rupee, is caused by the Fed’s belief that the recession in the
It is for this
reason that we observe a clear historical pattern: periods of
crisis in the
world economy are periods when third world economies get
delinked from it
(usually involving major political upheavals within the
countries to permit
such delinking). The Great Depression of the 1930s for
instance saw a spate of
political upheavals in the Latin American countries, resulting
in the
introduction of protectionist measures that facilitated a wave
of
industrialisation in that continent.
ALTERNATIVE
COURSE
The second course
before us consists precisely in such delinking, in rolling
back neo-liberalism,
by introducing import restrictions, and, since such
introduction will cause loss
of “investor confidence” and hence flight by finance capital,
imposing controls
on capital flows. Capital controls can take a variety of
forms, ranging from a
minimum period after coming into a country before capital can
move out, to
restrictions on the sale of assets (such as in China where
foreigners can sell
shares only to other foreigners), to a rationing of foreign
exchange outflow,
such as what India had for decades before liberalisation.
Those with a
neo-liberal mindset may feel that capital controls of this
sort, apart from
risking the wrath of the big capitalist powers, are also
questionable on the
grounds that they violate a solemn promise on the basis of
which capital had
flowed into the country in the first place. But wrath of the
big powers cannot
stand in the way of pursuing policies in the interests of the
people; indeed if
that had been the consideration then there should have been no
freedom struggle
against British colonialism. And as regards solemn promises,
not only do the
same considerations apply, namely that the interests of the
people take
precedence over all such promises, but additionally such
solemn promises are
systematically violated by the most powerful capitalist
country, the US. It
imposed an embargo, during its confrontation with the Islamic
regime, on
Besides, after the
East Asian crisis of 1997-8 when
The second course
will entail not only a quick end to the collapse of the rupee,
and hence an end
to cost-push inflation, but also a revival of demand for
domestic producers and
an immediate improvement in capacity utilisation and
employment in domestic
units. It will also provide elbow room to the government that
adopts this
course to undertake an alternative trajectory of pro-poor
growth without having
to worry about the “confidence” of international financiers.