People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 36 September 08, 2013 |
Is
Fiscal Profligacy The Cause
Of The Crisis?
Prabhat
Patnaik
YASHWANT Sinha,
finance minister under the NDA
government, was emphatic on television that the current
economic crisis of the
country, marked above all by a falling rupee, was because of
the excessively
large fiscal deficits that the government had run in the wake
of the collapse
of the housing bubble in the
It goes as follows.
Large fiscal deficits boost
aggregate demand in the economy which spills over into an
excess-demand-generated inflation, or into a larger current
account deficit on
the balance of payments, or some combination of the two. Hence
if we find the
current deficit widening substantially then the cause lies in
the large fiscal
deficits. In short, this argument blames excess domestic
aggregate demand for
the balance of payments problem, not world recession or trade
liberalisation.
DEFICIENCY OF
AGGREGATE DEMAND
What is striking
about the Indian economy at
present however is that even as the current account deficit
has widened, the
growth rate has slumped dramatically. In the last quarter of
2012-13 it was 4.8
percent and for the year as a whole it was 5 percent; in the
first quarter of
2013-4 it has fallen further to 4.4 percent. This slump in the
growth rate is
obviously on account of inadequate
aggregate demand: in the manufacturing sector for instance
where the growth
rate has been negative
for some
quarters (and was -1.2 percent in the April-June quarter over
the figure of the
preceding year), ie, where output has fallen in absolute
terms, no supply
constraints can possibly explain this fall. Supply
constraints, in the form of
capacity or infrastructure bottlenecks, can at best prevent
manufacturing
output from rising;
they cannot make
it fall. Even in
the service sector,
which hitherto had shown high growth, there is a palpable
slowing down, which
can only be explained in terms of a slowing down of demand. In
fact there is
direct evidence of a slowing down of demand, since gross fixed
capital
formation has witnessed an absolute fall over the year and
consumer expenditure
is virtually stagnant.
Far from there being
excess demand in the
economy, we have in short a deficiency of aggregate demand,
and an important reason
for the deficiency of
aggregate demand is the large current account deficit
itself. There are
four components of aggregate demand in any economy: private
consumption
expenditure, private investment, government expenditure (both
consumption and
investment) and net exports. A large current account deficit
which means a
large negative net
export, reduces
the level of aggregate demand in the economy, which is exactly
what has been
happening in the case of
Interestingly, the
one element of demand that
has kept up the level of activity in the economy, and with it
the growth rate,
is government expenditure. If government expenditure had been
lower than it
actually was, then the growth rate of the economy would have
been even lower
than its recent meagre level. This is also reflected in the
fact that the
component of the service sector that has shown the most
impressive growth rate
of late is the one that includes government expenditure.
The explanation of
the current economic crisis
in
The predicament of
the economy can be best
understood if we look at just one illustrative case, that of
BHEL. Because of
import liberalisation, foreign suppliers, especially from East
Asia, who have
the backing of their respective States, are taking away orders
within
What is true of BHEL
is even more true of large
numbers of domestic producers, especially in the small scale
sector, who are
driven to the wall by competition from
INSIDIOUS
ARGUMENT
A facile argument is
often put forward in this
context, namely that the depreciation of the rupee, caused by
the yawning
current account deficit, will improve the competitive position
of our producers
and hence restrict imports automatically. The falling rupee in
other words is
part of the self-correcting mechanism of the market itself,
and once the rupee
has fallen sufficiently the economy will reach an
“equilibrium” where the
current deficit will automatically shrink to a level equal to
what can be
financed through capital inflows.
This is a facile
argument for two reasons:
first, since the decline in the value of the rupee raises the
import price of
oil which gets passed on, the competitive advantage that might
accrue to
domestic producers through a fall in the value of the rupee is
offset to a considerable
extent by the rise in their costs owing to higher inflation.
Secondly, these
higher oil prices, and the cost-push inflation they generate,
affect the living
standards of the working people. To protect domestic producers
through a
currency depreciation therefore is a far more “costly” means
of doing so (in
human terms) than protecting them through raising tariff rates
in selected
spheres (where they do not have any such cost-push effects).
The
fiscal-deficit-as-the-cause-of-the-crisis
argument is not just wrong; it is insidious as well. It has
already given rise
to a veritable cacophony that subsidies must be cut in order
to curtail
government expenditure, so that the fiscal deficit is reined
in. This means inter
alia that the food security
legislation passed by parliament should be kept in abeyance
(and all existing
subsidies should be whittled down, or, what is a euphemism for
the same thing,
“better-targeted”).
This argument is not
only anti-people, and hence
insidious; it is also vacuous for the following reason. The
government already
has enormous food stocks which it does not even have enough
storage space for.
Suppose the government buys Rs 100 of FCI stocks through
running a fiscal
deficit, then since the FCI is part of the government itself,
there is no increase in
the net indebtedness
of the government, only a taking over
of FCI debt to banks by the government, which cannot
conceivably have any
impact whatsoever on the level of aggregate demand
(which is what the
neo-liberals are worried about).
Now, suppose the
government distributes these
stocks gratis to
the people. Some,
who did not have enough to eat
earlier, will eat more, but their aggregate demand for other
goods will not
change at all. But some who were earlier paying the market
price for grains,
but would now get free government grains, would have more
purchasing power in
their hands. In other words the only change in aggregate
demand that would
occur is through a switch from open market purchases by the
poor to receiving
government-supplied grains. Now, typically the additional
purchasing power in
their hands as a result of this switch will be spent by them
on a range of
simple locally available goods, with very little import
content, which will
generate larger local employment and output. And to the extent
there is some
spill-over to imports of such additional purchasing power, it
can be easily
prevented by raising the tariffs on the concerned imported
goods.
In other words
objecting to the food security
measure on the grounds that the fiscal deficit will be
enlarged thereby misses
the point that there
will be no increase
in the net external indebtedness of the government as
long as FCI stocks
exist. And the import-spillover effect of any downstream
increase in aggregate
demand can be handled by appropriate import tariffs, which
need not even
violate WTO rules.
Of course, the
concern with the fiscal deficit
has less to do with its actual implications than with the
“reaction of
financial markets”. But if people have to go hungry for
financial markets to be
appeased, then that is an argument for liberating the economy
from subservience
to financial markets.