People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 31 August 04 , 2013 |
Brinda Karat SINCE the CPI(M)
is a strong
proponent of a legally mandated right to food, the
question may be raised as to
why the Party has strongly criticised the Food Security
Ordinance (FSO). There
are three reasons. First, coming as it does on the eve of
the parliament
session, it shows contempt for parliament and is an
unacceptable attempt of the
government to impose its writ on parliament. Second, the
ordinance contains two
new clauses concerning state governments without any
consultation with them
thus undermining the federal structure of the
constitution. Third, on the
substantive issues regarding the provision of food
security the ordinance
ignores the amendments, which were suggested by several
parties, including the CPI(M),
and circulated in the last session of parliament. On the
other hand, it retains
the extremely flawed provisions in the earlier Bill, which
have been discussed
in these columns in some detail. These clauses reduce even
present entitlements
for a large section of the population. Further, the
ordinance like the Bill
before it, does not protect, let alone build on the
various food schemes
operating well in at least twelve major states. The effort of
the CPI(M) both inside
and outside parliament has been to push for amendments to
the Bill, now
ordinance, to prevent irrational exclusions of populations
equally food
insecure and to put in place a legal guarantee for a
universalised right to
food security which will help redress the grave injustices
which have led to
India being home to the largest malnourished population in
the whole world. The Food
Security Ordinance
introduces a new sub-clause in Clause 10.1.(b) of the
earlier Bill regarding a
time-frame. It states “State Government may, as soon as
possible, but within
such period not exceeding 180 days after the commencement
of the ordinance,
identify the eligible households in accordance with the
guidelines framed under
this sub-section.” The state
governments will be
required to complete two processes. First, the Ordinance
has lowered the
entitlement to 5 kgs per capita and eliminated the 35 kg
entitlement per
household. Thus a five member BPL family will get only 25
kgs, losing 10 kgs
from its present entitlement. A four member BPL family say
in a state like
Kerala where family size is smaller, will lose 15 kgs from
its present
entitlement. To implement this reduced entitlement, it
will be necessary for a
state government to identify the number of individuals in
each family. Secondly, except
for Antodaya card
holders, there will have to be a new verification for
“eligible beneficiaries”,
since the targeted system remains though in a new form. Thus the time
framework should first
have been discussed with state governments rather than
including it in the
ordinance. The CPI(M) will move an amendment to this
effect. The sub-section
in the clause, which
was also there in the earlier Bill, states that it is the
state governments who
decide the criteria for identification. The central
government is claiming that
in the said clause the demand of the state government for
the right to decide
the criteria has been accepted. This is a typical half
truth to conceal the
assault on the rights of the states in this ordinance. The
government
propaganda is that the Bill will cover 75 percent of the
rural population in
all states and 50 percent of the urban population, coming
to an average of 67
percent in all states. This is not the case. It is a 67
percent average for the
total national population divided differently in the
states on the basis of
criteria decided by the Planning Commission. The state wise
lists of the inclusion
ratio (base 2011-12) have already been sent from the
Planning Commission to the
food ministry. The Planning Commission’s state wise
“poverty quotas” for rural
and urban areas is given in the table below in the first
two columns. The third
column is a calculation of the total percentage of
beneficiaries in each state (rural
and urban) on the basis of the Planning Commission’s
inclusion ratios. Inclusion
ratio in % base 2011-12 Percentage
of total population included in FSB INDIA/STATE/UT Rural Urban NCT OF
37.69 43.58 43.43 KERALA 52.63 39.50 46.36 HARYANA 54.61 41.05 49.89 TAMIL
NADU 62.55 37.79 50.55 54.79 44.83 51.06 HIMACHAL
PRADESH 56.23 30.99 53.69 ANDHRA
PRADESH 60.96 41.14 54.32 UTTARAKHAND 65.26 52.05 61.22 76.32 45.34 62.31 74.64 48.25 63.40 RAJASTHAN 69.08 53.00 65.08 KARNATAKA 76.04 49.36 65.75 74.47 47.55 65.88 75.00 50.00 67.21 TRIPURA 74.75 49.54 68.15 MADHYA
PRADESH 80.10 62.61 75.27 UTTAR
PRADESH 79.56 64.43 76.19 ODISHA 82.17 55.77 77.77 CHHATTISGARH 84.25 58.98 78.38 JHARKHAND 86.48 60.20 80.16 84.17 60.35 80.82 85.12 74.53 83.92 As can be seen
from the table, out of
21 selected states, 13 states will have an inclusion
percentage less than the
national average of 67 percent, including Andhra Pradesh,
Tamilnadu and Kerala
while eight states will have a higher percentage including
Uttar Pradesh, There are
several problems with this
list and the approach behind it. ANOTHER FRAUDULENT EXERCISE? How have these
figures been decided?
What is the criteria used by the Planning Commission?
Government spokespersons
claim that the discredited Planning Commission methodology
of poverty estimates
which is the basis for the
APL/BPL
divisions has been given up for purposes of the FSO. But
in fact, the same
ratios which were used in the past to distribute quotas to
the states have been
retained by the Planning Commission with some
“adjustments” to make it a
national average of 67 percent. The right of the
state governments to
“decide criteria” is utterly compromised by these caps set
by the Planning Commission.
The guidelines drafted by the state governments have to be
such so as to ensure
exclusion of the population so as to limit the coverage to
the percentage
decided by the Planning Commission. Say for example, a state government
frames guidelines, that
all sections of those workers who are in the unorganised
sector with no fixed
income will be eligible for benefits under the law. This
is a perfectly logical
criteria for automatic inclusion, since workers in the
unorganised sector do
not have a fixed income or the benefit of Dearness
Allowance and are most
vulnerable to high food inflation, malnutrition and
hunger. Identification on
the basis of such a guideline could mean that the numbers
would cross the urban
inclusion percentage lakshman rekha decreed by the
Planning Commission for that
particular state. So
the state
government cannot use the criteria of its choice since it
may mean higher
figures of beneficiaries than decreed by the Planning
Commission. It is a
mockery therefore to claim that state governments are
given the right to decide
the criteria. Informally, the central government is
telling the states to
use the data being collected through the questionnaires
being used for the
Social and Caste Census for the exclusion. It is also being suggested that the
Planning Commission will
on the basis of the SECC census data available for most
states, help the state
governments to “doctor” their guidelines so as to “fit in”
with the percentages
given, by asking only such questions as will ensure that
percentages add up.
This is a most cynical exercise which is as fraudulent as
the discredited
poverty lines of the Planning Commission. ELIMINATING THE RIGHTS OF APL CARD HOLDERS What will be the result if these “state
quotas” are
implemented? As is known in at least 12 major states,
governments have covered
a much larger population in their food security schemes
than advocated through
the fraudulent numbers put out by the Planning Commission.
This has meant a
larger number of BPL cards have been issued and more
people have had access to
foodgrains at subsidised prices in these states. These
States include
Tamilnadu,, Karnataka Kerala, Andhra Pradesh, Jharkhand,
Orissa Bengal,
Tripura, Rajastahan, Madhya Pradesh, Chattisgarh, APL card holders have also had access to
foodgrains, in these
and other states. If the state governments actually
implement the law in its
present form it will mean the cancellation of the rights
of crores of
these card
holders. According to the food ministry figures
(Pg 53, Foodgrains
Bulletin, May 2013) as on March 31, 2013, there are 13.17
crore APL ration
cards in the country, 8.68 crore BPL cards and 2.43 crore
AAY cards adding up
to a total of 24.29 crore cards. Considering that there
are 24.70 households
according to the 2011 census, if the ration card figures
are correct this makes
it a very high coverage of the population who have ration
cards. The government charges that there are a
large number of
“ghost cards.” It is true that the numbers do not match
up, because there are
still substantial numbers of people without any ration
cards. Also in a state
like Implementing the quotas set up by the
Planning Commission
will mean the elimination of the rights of APL card
holders to subsidised
foodgrains. It needs to be reiterated that the above
poverty line (APL) ration
card holders have been designated as such by utterly
fraudulent data. Their
vulnerability to high food inflation is shown by the fact
that a large
percentage of APL cardholders are actually lifting their
quotas. The offtake of
rice by APL card holders has been consistently above 70
percent and upto 90
percent between 2010-2011 to 2013-2014 (upto April 2013).
The legal mandate under the FSO is for
the state governments
to “adjust” to another fraud being committed through
irrational exclusions of
people. Will it be possible for any state government to do
this? The utter hypocrisy of the central
government lies in the
clause 32.2 in the ordinance which states “Notwithstanding
anything contained
in this ordinance, the state government may, continue with
or formulate
nutrition based plans or schemes providing for benefits
higher than the
benefits provided in this ordinance, from their own
resources.” In fact it should
be the other way around. Any food security Bill for the
country should use as
its benchmark the better and “higher benefits” existing in
different states.
For this, the only way would be a universal public
distribution system backed
up by the law. Instead what will happen is that the state
governments will be
burdened by high costs of procuring the grains they will
require to maintain
their better system of food security. Therefore the centre
is shifting its
responsibility and the financial burdens to the states. Apart from the
elimination of rights
of a substantial section affecting all states, there will
be a varied impact on
other issues. The following assessment is based on various
reports of the food
ministry. It may require correction for certain states.
Also the ratio of rice
and wheat allocations which have state wise differences
which are subject to
change must also be factored in. The states which
have not initiated
any pro-poor food schemes but have accepted the central
government BPL numbers
and prices include Maharashtra, Uttar Pradesh, Bihar,
Assam, Punjab, Haryana,
Himachal Pradesh. In these states BPL families will lose
out on the
allocations. At present they are getting 35kgs but will
now get 25 kgs. The
current market price of common rice is around 25 rupees a
kilo. Thus they will
incur an expenditure of 250 rupees for ten kilos to
maintain the pre-FSO level
of 35 kgs. For wheat (flour) present market prices are 20
rupees a kilo or an
added expenditure of 200 rupees for 10 kilos. However the BPL
families in these
states will gain through price benefit offered in the FSO.
At present they are
paying an average of six rupees per kilo of rice. The FSO
offers rice at three
rupees a kilo. For twenty five kilos of rice they will
make a saving of 75
rupees from what they are paying now. For wheat the
average is 4.50 rupees a kg
at present. The price of wheat in the FSO is two rupees a
kg.. Thus the saving
on 25 kgs of wheat would be 82.50 rupees. Thus if a five
member BPL family is
to maintain the 35 kgs level there would be a net loss in
monetary terms after
the implementation of the FSO to the extent of 185 rupees
for rice and 117. 50
rupees for wheat per family per month. This is the
additional expenditure at
present market prices which as we know are
relentlessly increasing. In addition, in
particular UP and
Bihar a benefit accruing from the FSO will be that a
substantial number of APL
families will benefit by gaining access to the FSO through
the inclusion ratios
for these states. Tamilnadu
has a unique
universalised system where 20 kgs of rice is given free of
cost to everyone.
After the FSO all “eligible” families will have to be
given 5 kgs more. However
the inclusion ratio for Tamilnadu is set at just 50.55 per
cent so there will
be a drastic reduction in the allocations from the centre.
If Tamilnadu wants
to maintain the universal system it will have to buy more
much grain in the
open market at high costs. This is clearly unfair, unjust
and a mockery of food
security for the people of Tamilnadu. The state government will save some
money through the price
differential between the central government’s issue price
and the state subsidy
of free rice. At present it is buying APL rice at over
eight rupees a kilo and
BPL rice at over four rupees a kg from the centre and
giving it free to the
people. Now rice will be available from the centre at
three rupees a kg. But in
total the cost borne by the state government will go up. In Kerala there
will be a loss on all
three counts, cut in allocations, higher prices, as well
as exclusion of APL
card holders as the coverage in Kerala is near universal.
In Tripura also,
there will be a cut on all three counts as will be so in
Orissa and Jharkhand. In Andhra Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh
where the allocation is
20 kgs for a five member BPL family, there will be a gain
of 5kgs but at higher
prices, since rice is available at two rupees. In other states like Chattisgarh, The main question which arises is how
can the central
government claim to be providing food security as on many
counts entitlements
are being cut which will cause food insecurity ? The
ordinance in Clause 10 (b)
states that “the state government shall continue to
receive the allocations of
foodgrains from the central government under the existing
targeted public
distribution system, till the identification of
households is complete.”
In other words once the fraudulent ratios of the Planning
Commission are
implemented and “eligible” beneficiaries identified, the
allocations will be
cut and allocations made only according to the figures
given by the Planning
Commission. This is a most dangerous clause which must be amended so
that at least the present
allocations will not be reduced for any state. ACTUAL CRITERIA In fact, the actual criteria is that the
central government
has decided the “quotas” simply on the basis of what it
wants to spend – of
gaining the maximum political mileage with the least
amount of additional
expenditure rather than of any moral or ethical
responsibility to meet the
needs of food security. The highly inflated figures of the
amount of money required
for the FSO of over 3 percent of GDP by right wing
economists is laughable. The
food ministry has calculated that with the increased
population in 2011 over
2001, (which would have meant an increased expenditure
regardless of the FSO)
as well as the price difference between present BPL prices
and the proposed
price in the FSO, added expenditure would come to an
additional 24,000 crore
rupees over the approximately One lakh crore being spent
on the food subsidy. The entire cost is less than one percent
of the GDP. By cutting down the BPL entitlement by
10 kgs per family and
by eliminating a large number of APL cardholders from the
list of beneficiaries
the government is juggling around the same amount of
foodgrains presently being
allocated to the PDS. According to estimates given by the
food ministry, the
implementation of the food security law will not require
any substantial
increase in the foodgrain requirement. The annual allocations to the PDS for
all ration card holders
has ranged from 48.87 million tones in 2011-2012 to 50. 46
million tones in
2012-2013. If one includes all the allocations including
the additional for
welfare schemes like mid-day meal scheme, the total
allocation of foodgrains
for 2013-2014 is 53.12 million tonnes. The calculation of
the ministry is that
the FSO will require at most around 4 million tonnes more. For the last several years India has a
buffer stock of
foodgrains more than double its requirement. As on June 1,
2013, the stocks
with the FCI and State agencies were 7.76 million tonnes
while the buffer stock
requirement is just 3.19 million tonnes. The expenditure
on maintaining these
stocks is also high. The government could have easily
maintained the
entitlement of 7 kgs per capita instead of cutting it down
to 5 kgs SECOND NEW CLAUSE : IN THE RULES As part of the procedure towards
implementation of an Act,
the government has to frame Rules for its concrete
implementation. The Bill in
its main body has a chapter on introduction of ‘reforms’
in the PDS. The first
draft of the Bill placed before the Standing Committee had
an obnoxious clause
which linked the rights of APL card holders to get the
benefits of the law, to
the actions of the state government to implement the
reforms including cash
transfers instead of foodgrains. After strong objection
the linkage was deleted
in the Bill placed before parliament. The redrafted clause
read “ that the
central and state governments shall endeavour… to
progressively introduce
reforms… such as cash transfers etc.” No time frame was
set. In the ordinance however there is a
reintroduction of the
mandatory nature of introduction of cash transfers this
time in the section
about the right of the central government to frame the
rules. The clause 38.1
(d) reads “
the Rules may provide for
all or any of the following .. “introducing cash transfer
schemes to the
targeted beneficiaries in lieu of their foodgrains
entitlements in such areas
and manner .. as may be prescribed by the central
government. As is known the Rules do not require any
consultation with
the state governments. Thus this provision in the law will
make it mandatory
for state governments to implement the cash transfer
scheme even if they oppose
it, if the central government so decides.
Moreover since the Rules are framed by the central
government the states
will have no say at all on this important issue. Thus the Bill is being used as an
instrument to make it
compulsory for all state governments to accept the UPA
version of “reform” in
the PDS overriding the objections of the states even where
it concerns direct
cash transfers as a substitute for foodgrains. IMPROVE THE BILL The earlier critiques of the Bill remain
valid for the
ordinance too. The CPI(M) had in the last session of
parliament moved amendments
to all those flawed clauses. The amendments included:. (1) The Bill retains the targeted system
by excluding 25
percent in rural areas and 50 percent in urban areas. The
Party’s amendment is
‘to make it universal excluding only income tax payees.” (2)
The Bill is limited only to foodgrains. The CPI(M)
amendment is to
include “ adequate quantities of sugar, pulses and cooking
oil.” (3) The
allocation in the Bill is
only for 5kgs of foodgrains per person per month. The
CPI(M) amendment is ; “7
kilograms of foodgrains per month or 35 kilograms per
household, whichever is
higher.” (4)The Bill in
Schedule 1 puts the
price of rice at three rupees a kilo. The CPI(M) amendment
is for “Rs 2 per kg
for rice.” (5) The Bill
includes a clause that
the current prices will be valid for only three years
after which they may be
raised as long as it is not above the MSP price for
foodgrains. This is a most
obnoxious clause as it is designed to cut the subsidy on
issue price of
foodgrains in the PDS, wrongly linking the issue prices to
MSP. The CPI(M)
amendment is to delete this clause in the Schedule 1 (6) In all
sections where the central
government has arrogated to itself the right to take
arbitrary decisions,
including those on cost sharing, the CPI(M) amendment is “
only in consultation
with state governments.” The CPI(M)s fresh amendment will
include the words “in
consultation and with the agreement of state governments.”
This is necessary
because the Bill is highly centralised and with the
additions in the ordinance,
agreement of the state government is essential before any
step is taken. (7) The present
Bill has omitted the
earlier clauses for food security for particularly
deprived sections through
community kitchens. The CPI(M) amendment is to retain
these clauses and for the
cost to be born by central government. (8) A fresh
amendment will include a
clause that present allocations will not be reduced. (9)Amendment to
remove the reference
to cash transfers and AADHAR. The Food
Security Ordinance
NEW
CLAUSE: IDENTIFICATION
WITHIN
180 DAYS
WHO
ACTUALLY
DECIDES
CRITERIA?
STATE
VARIATIONS
OTHER
STATES