People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 31 August 04 , 2013 |
The Long-Term Crisis of Capitalism Prabhat Patnaik
CAPITALISM is a
bizarre system. When
the “going is good”, when the economy is expanding,
capitalists expect this
expansion to continue and make growing investments, which
actually make this
expansion continue. In fact they develop euphoric
expectations which make them even
more reckless in undertaking projects, and the boom keeps
getting more and more
pronounced. But once this euphoria is deflated for some
reason, the bubble
bursts, investment is cut back, profits fall, which leads to
a further cut-back
in investment, and the economy enters a downturn. In the
downturn, unemployment
increases, wages are cut, which further cuts down demand,
which makes the
downturn even more acute. When and how the economy comes out
of the downturn,
when and how capitalists’ spirits start reviving is not
clear. But when it
does, a new boom gets started and gathers momentum. This has been the
story of capitalism
since its birth. But, apart from the question of how exactly
the downturn comes
to an end, through a revival of capitalists’ spirits, there
is a second crucial
question that this account leaves unanswered, namely,
through these booms and
slumps, why does the
economy experience
any net expansion at all? Why does it grow
through these periodic booms and slumps? The fact that
it has done so is
not in doubt, but the question is what mechanism is there to
explain why it has
done so? Bourgeois economics is hard put to find any
internal mechanism within
the system that can explain such growth. Indeed
it avoids the problem altogether by merely assuming Say’s
Law, that there is
never a problem of aggregate demand in a capitalist economy
because “supply
creates its own demand”. In such a case however there should
be no recessions
or slumps ever, and capitalism should be crisis-free, which
is patently absurd. EXTERNAL PROPS When we look at
the actual history of
capitalism, it becomes clear that the cause of growth within
the system has
been the availability of certain external props for
capitalism. Throughout the
nineteenth century, right until the First World War, the
external prop that was
available to the system and made it function relatively
satisfactorily, causing
what is often referred to as a “long boom” between the
mid-nineteenth century
and the First World War, was the “colonial system”. This worked as
follows: a vast
migration of European population took place to the “new
world” where land was
grabbed from the local inhabitants, so that the migrants
could set themselves
up as “farmers”. Alongside such migration of people there
was also a migration
of capital from Europe, which was extracted from the
colonies of possession,
such as This killed three
birds with one
stone for the capitalist core in By the same token,
however, the
colonies suffered twice over. First, taking the above
example, Rs 100 of their
goods (mainly raw materials and primary commodities) were
taken away from them
in exchange for goods which only substituted those already
being produced
domestically and whose import thus caused
deindustrialisation and domestic
unemployment. The immediate victims of this first suffering
were the artisans
and the craftsmen displaced through deindustrialisation (and
they in turn
raised land rents by trying to lease in land and lowered
wages by swelling the
labour supply). The impact of the second suffering was
directly on the
peasantry (who were the main primary producers), since Rs 50
of produce
constituting the “drain” was simply snatched from them in
the form of taxes. This arrangement
worked well for the
metropolis until the First World War. It
solved both the problems of capitalism mentioned earlier.
It provided the
system with an external prop of the sort required to ensure
that it experiences
net expansion, ie, growth. At the same time, it also meant
that downturns when
they occurred could be quickly overcome. In fact the system
experienced growth
precisely because the periodic
downturns were brief and shallow while the periodic booms
were pronounced and
prolonged. This latter phenomenon was the mechanism for
growth. The breakdown of
this arrangement was
a major factor underlying the Great Depression of the 1930s,
both its depth and
its protracted nature. In the post-second world war period
when the old
arrangement had ended for good, both because the “frontier”
had been reached in
the “new world”, and no more European migration on the scale
that had occurred
earlier was possible, and also because the colonies of
possession were in the
process of acquiring independence, a new arrangement was put
in place, and this
was State intervention in “demand management”. This was not
as good an
arrangement as the “colonial system” for solving the
problems of metropolitan
capitalism. It only solved the problem of deficiency of
aggregate demand, but
not of obtaining primary commodities and raw materials on
the cheap: it opened
up the possibility that if the newly-independent colonies
got together they
could raise the prices of such commodities (as happened
later with OPEC). But this latter
problem was not of
immediate concern since the primary producing third world
countries did not get
together; the resolution of
the problem of aggregate demand, under these circumstances,
caused a massive
boom, the biggest over a comparable period in the history of
capitalism, which
is why this period from say 1950 to 1973 has been called
“the Golden age of
capitalism”. A major feature of
contemporary
capitalism is that even
this second external prop is also gone. (The State whose
intervention had propped
up the system is “external” only in the sense of not being
directly a part of
the base). Globalised finance ensures that the State
operates exclusively in
its own interests and in accordance with its own caprices;
and these demand
that the State budget be balanced, with at most a fixed
ratio of fiscal deficit
to GDP, and that State taxation (of the rich at least) be
kept down. Hence the
capacity of the State to pursue “countercyclical policies”,
eg, a policy of
increased State spending in a period of recession, is
undermined. The demand
for “austerity” in the midst of the current global recession
is an expression
of this predilection of finance capital, and underscores the
fact that this
external prop can no longer be used under capitalism. NO EARLY END TO THE CRISES It may appear
strange at first sight that
the system undermines in this fashion its own external prop,
but since
capitalism is not a “planned system”, and since the
hostility of finance to an
interventionist State (except if the intervention is in its
own exclusive
interest) is spontaneous, arising from its basic need to
preserve its social
legitimacy by cultivating the belief that the State cannot
do the job of the
capitalists, there is nothing strange about it. Thus the hallmark
of contemporary
capitalism is that it is without any external prop that can
ensure its
long-term growth, and hence by implication an early end to
the crises, such as
the current one, that afflict it. This does not mean
that it will
necessarily remain submerged in crisis for ever. What it
means is that, first,
since getting out of the crisis is no longer something that
the availability of
external props can quickly ensure, as they did in the “long
nineteenth century”
(ending with the First World War) or during the so-called
“Golden Age” of the
fifties and the sixties, it may take long to do so; and,
second, when the
system does somehow get out of this crisis and a new boom
gets generated, since
the basis of it will only be the capitalists’ own
expectations, rather than
anything more solid and tangible like colonial markets or
investment
opportunities in the “new world” or State fiscal stimulus,
its collapse will
once again take the system back to square one. There will be
no particular
reason to expect positive net expansion
of the system. The comparable
situation to today’s
is the period of the Great Depression when the system was
again, temporarily,
without any external props. The old colonial system had
ceased to play its
earlier role (because of the closing of the “frontier”), and
State intervention
in demand management had not yet come into vogue. The Great
Depression ended in
Today not only is
there no external
prop actually at hand, but there is not even the sign of one
on the horizon.
This is unlike during the Great Depression when many were
already demanding
State intervention and It is this which constitutes the long-term crisis of
capitalism, the fact that
the system is in an
impasse, without even an inkling of a possible way out. It
can at its best
only mark time through
bubble-based booms and pricked-bubble slumps. When such a
bubble will re-form
nobody knows; and there is no reason why its re-formation
will cause growth of
the system. This has important
implications for