People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 24 June 16, 2013 |
Globalisation
Widens Inequality in Wage Pattern: ILO Study Sukomal Sen IT was predicted by many
bourgeois economists not very long ago that
globalisation, the growth of
international trade and capital flows, would
reduce inequalities in the developing
countries. The standard trade theory predicted
that a fall in trade barriers
would trigger massive exports of goods that used a
large number of relatively
low skill workers, the most abundant production
factor in developing countries.
Hence, it was expected that in these countries,
globalisation would raise the
demand for, and wages of, relatively low skill
workers, and thereby reduce wage
inequalities. The plausibility of this prediction
was reinforced by the earlier
experiences of some countries and territories,
notably the REALITY DIFFERENT
FROM EXPECTATIONS However, the story of
globalisation in the 1980s and 1990s has been
quite different. Reviews of the relevant
literature show that all existing measures about
inequality in developing
countries point to an overall increase in
inequality over the last three
decades, which in some cases was quite severe. In
fact, with the notable
exception of The minimum wage is
another key labour market institution. It
means setting a wage floor applicable to wage
earners, ensuring that they receive
a minimum level of pay protection.
Therefore, it mostly affects the low end
of the wage distribution, whereas the other
wage-setting institutions (such as
trade unions and collective bargaining) affect the
whole distribution. Although
most countries in the world have some form of
minimum wage, the characteristics
of minimum wage schemes vary across nations,
making the elaboration of
comparable data sets on minimum wages a difficult
task. Minimum wage fixing
procedures (including government legislation,
collective bargaining), the
coverage rate, eligibility and other operational
details all change from
country to country. There can also be different
minima, according to hourly,
daily, weekly or monthly time frames. Outside the
single minimum wage, reduced
or sub-minimum rates for specific group of
workers, such as young people, can
also be set. COLLECTIVE
BARGAINING, MINIMUM WAGES IN
A study by the
International Labour Organisation (ILO) --- Perspectives
on Labour Economics for Development ---
shows that workers being part of a
trade union in The overall collective
bargaining coverage in Another important area of
wage policy relates to the design of minimum wages
in The ILO estimated that
partial coverage together with non-compliance
have resulted in a situation where
73 to 76 million salaried and casual workers, out
of a total of about 175
million, were being paid below the statutory
minimum wages, This calls for a
rethinking of the way minimum wages in India are
fixed and implemented, moving
in the direction of a simpler system with better
implementation and broader
coverage. Certain key statistics,
however, such as the ratio of the minimum wage to
the average wage, are often
used to capture the effects of minimum wages on
employment or on the
distribution of earnings in different countries.
In developing countries, given
the limited collective bargaining coverage and the
challenges the trade unions
face to organise low paid workers, the minimum
wage scheme can play an
important role in protecting the purchasing power
of low paid workers.
Moreover, it is often used as a reference for
other worker benefits and by
informal workers and employers (the lighthouse
effect, which refers to the
minimum wage used as a reference point for
settling wages even in the informal
sector). The main
objective of the minimum wage is to improve the
welfare of low wage earners. Whether the wage
actually achieves its intended
purpose is another issue that has been the
subject of great controversy for
several years, says the ILO. UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE The following section
begins with elements of cross-country comparisons,
and then describes the main
theoretical predictions of the effects of minimum
wages; Finally, the main
empirical findings are presented. A large number
of studies, both theoretical
and empirical, have examined the effects of the
minimum wage. Theory provides
unambiguous predictions only in relation to a
competitive labour market.
Empirical evidence provides mixed results,
depending on the country, the level
of the minimum wage, the existence of a single or
several minimum wages, the
methods of analysis and the economic model used.
Thus, empirical evidence may
actually show contradictory findings. Unemployment compensation
can be provided by insurance or assistance
schemes. In most European and OECD
countries (except, Australia and New Zealand),
unemployed people receive
unemployment benefits through unemployment
insurance (UI) schemes that provide
at least partial income replacement, maintain a
certain standard of living and
provide workers with the means to search for a
suitable job during the
transition period. Such unemployment benefits are
typically funded by
contributory schemes and offer compensation
related to the previous earnings of
the beneficiary after a qualifying period, mostly
for a limited period of time.
The income support
provided by the unemployment benefit schemes can
play an important role in
cushioning the social impacts of an economic
recession and serve as an
important automatic stabiliser during a showdown.
In addition, public
unemployment assistance systems exist in a number
of countries (especially in
high income nations) but play only a residual role
in closing the relatively
small coverage gaps. These are usually not based
on prior earnings but are flat
rate non-contributory cash transfers to those who
are still unemployed, either
once their entitlements to unemployment benefits
have expired, or when they
have never been entitled. Income support to the
long-term unemployed and their
families is often taken over by general
means-tested social assistance
schemes. The absence of
unemployment insurance or other statutory income
support programmes for the
unemployed in most low and middle-income countries
has often made
mandated severance payments the only available
protection in the event of job
loss and has led to higher employment protection
legislation, at least de jure
protection for those workers in
the formal economy. However, while both severance
payments and unemployment
insurance do provide income compensation to job
losers, they arc different
instruments with different approaches:
unemployment insurance schemes arc
worker-oriented (e.g. linked to the individual
status of being unemployed),
while severance payment schemes arc rather
job-oriented (e.g. linked to the
specificity of job matches and the value of
seniority). Moreover, differences
also exist related to their financing and the
level of security provided.
Severance pay is based on employers’ liability,
while unemployment insurance is
financed from pooled contributions paid by workers
and employers. The latter
does not entail any additional financial pressure
on ailing enterprises (unlike
severance payments, which in practice are often
not delivered to workers) and
tends to provide protection also for workers with
shorter periods of job tenure
and lower wage levels. Moreover, severance pay is
a lump sum, while
unemployment insurance provides periodical
benefits, usually for a prescribed
duration. Finally, severance pay tends to be more
strongly related to the wage
level and job tenure in a specific enterprise than
unemployment benefits, which
affects the level of protection and labour
mobility. Unemployment
insurance systems exist, however, in HYBRID SCHEMES So several countries,
typically the Central and South American ones,
have introduced hybrid systems
to combine these two approaches: various reforms
took place in that region
during the 2000s to allow individual savings
accounts or experience-rated
unemployment insurance, which combines layoff
taxes paid by firms (a form of
employment protection with collective unemployment
insurance (for example in
Chile from 2002 to 2005 and in the Bolivarian
Republic of Venezuela from 2002
to 2005). These private schemes often provide
complementary support, such as
the Chilean unemployment insurance system which
combines the individual
capitalisation accounts (unemployment insurance
savings accounts, UISA), from
which the contributions accumulated by the worker
are paid out on Job
separation) with a subsidised solidarity fund for
those dismissed for economic
reasons (to which the employer and the state
contribute). Again, it is
important to highlight the fact that the UISA, UI
and severance pay are not
alternative forms of income support and that each
instrument has its own
features and limits. UISA schemes are based on
mandatory individual savings.
They are usually marred with extremely low
take-up, both for workers and
employers, even for those workers in the informal
economy with relatively good
contributory capacities, and more so for those
with low contributory capacities
and those who face disadvantages in the labour
market (often women and various
vulnerable groups). Further challenges linked to
private individualised savings
options relate to possible regressive effects, low
coverage and high
administrative costs. Within the labour market
package, the unemployment benefit schemes
(contributory and non-contributory)
aim at maintaining income levels after losing a
job, providing insurance to
maintain consumption levels and time to search for
a new job. They are part of
the labour market regulations that have been
argued to drive cross-country
differences in labour market outcomes (in
particular unemployment patterns). As
previously indicated, unemployment compensation
systems vary quite dramatically
between countries and features with respect to the
level of unemployment
benefits, their duration and the conditions of
eligibility, which may impact
both firms' decisions to hire and fire workers in
response to changing economic
circumstances and employees' decisions to stay or
leave their current Jobs.
According to theoretical arguments, unemployment
benefit schemes provide good income
protection to formal sector workers and can help
reduce poverty. However, they
also suffer from two potential shortcomings: they
leave out informal sector
workers and can create moral hazard that increases
work disincentives and
Imposes efficiency costs. The lesson we may
draw from the ILO study is that trade union
struggle is the biggest determinant for
achieving minimum wage as well as
unemployment benefits in the era of neo-liberal
globalisation where the capitalist
governments would not resort to any labour
welfare scheme out of their own
volition, as maximisation of profit is the aim
of world capitalism.