People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 23 June 09, 2013 |
The Growth Slump
Prabhat Patnaik
THE
Ministry of Statistics
and Programme Implementation released the GDP figures for
the fourth quarter of
2012-13, and hence for the financial year as a whole, on May
31. And it shows a
GDP growth rate of only 5 per cent for 2012-13 over 2011-12.
These GDP figures
have 2004-05 as the base, which means that the overall
growth rate is
calculated as a weighted average of sectoral growth rates,
taking the weights
of the different sectors as they were in 2004-05. Since the
service sector has
been the fastest growing sector in the economy of late, its
weight too has been
rising. If we take an earlier base year, for which the
weights of the material
production sectors were higher, then the GDP growth rate
will be even smaller.
WHY GDP ESTIMATES
MUST EXCLUDE SERVICES
Indeed,
the material
production sectors alone are often considered to be a better
indicator of the
economy’s output growth than the conventional GDP estimates
which include
services as well. This is so for at least four reasons:
First,
a very substantial
part of service sector “output” estimation is statistically
extremely
ill-founded; indeed it is no more than guess work.
Secondly,
even
conceptually it is difficult to separate “transfer payment”
made by one person to
another, which is not included in GDP estimates, from,
“payment for services.” Typically,
“payment for services” is supposed to involve compensation
for some
“satisfaction” given by the payee to the one who pays; the
giver of this
“satisfaction” becomes a “service provider” by virtue of
this act of giving
“satisfaction.” But if giving alms to a beggar provides
“satisfaction” to the alms-giver,
then the beggar becomes a “service provider” by this
definition, in which case
the alms given should be counted not as transfer payment,
but rather as part of
GDP. Since it is impossible to distinguish between “transfer
payment” and
“payment for services,” many economists are in favour of
excluding services altogether
from GDP estimates.
Thirdly,
there is no
independent means of estimating service sector output other
than what is paid
for the service. Thus the output of the service sector
called “public
administration” goes up if the salaries of government
employees are increased because
of the Pay Commission; hence the GDP goes up even without
any additional effort
having been made by anyone.
Fourthly,
and even more
significantly, service sector output goes up when the degree
of exploitation of
the working people in the economy goes up, so that increased
exploitation
appears perversely as increased GDP. Suppose, for instance,
that in a purely peasant
economy, the output of agriculture remains unchanged at 100;
the original
surplus handed to landlords was 50 which they used for
maintaining 50
musclemen. The GDP as estimated conventionally would be 150,
of which 100 would
be in agriculture and 50 in services (the musclemen). Now,
if the surplus
extracted from the peasants goes up to 60 and 60 musclemen
are employed with
it, then the GDP would go up from 150 to 160. An increase in
the exploitation
of producers appears ironically as an increase in
production!
For
these reasons, the
Table 1: Quarterly Growth
Rates of GDP by Sector of Origin
Item |
2011-12 |
2012-13 |
||||||
|
Q1 |
Q2 |
Q3 |
Q4 |
Q1 |
Q2 |
Q3 |
Q4 |
Agriculture, forestry & fishing |
5.4 |
3.2 |
4.1 |
2.0 |
2.9 |
1.7 |
1.8 |
1.4 |
Mining & quarrying |
-0.4 |
-5.3 |
-2.6 |
5.2 |
0.4 |
1.7 |
-.7 |
-3 |
Manufacturing |
7.4 |
3.1 |
0.7 |
0.1 |
-1 |
0.1 |
2.5 |
2.6 |
Electricity, gas & water supply |
6.6 |
8.4 |
7.7 |
3.5 |
6.2 |
3.2 |
4.5 |
2.8 |
Construction |
3.8 |
6.5 |
6.9 |
5.1 |
7 |
3.1 |
2.9 |
4.4 |
trade, hotels, transport &
communication |
9.5 |
7 |
6.9 |
5.1 |
6.1 |
6.8 |
6.4 |
6.2 |
Finance, insurance, real estate &
business services |
11.6 |
12.3 |
11.4 |
11.3 |
9.3 |
8.3 |
7.8 |
9.1 |
Community, social & personal
services |
3.5 |
6.5 |
6.8 |
6.8 |
8.9 |
8.4 |
5.6 |
4.0 |
GDP At Factor Cost |
7.5 |
6.5 |
6 |
5.1 |
5.4 |
5.2 |
4.7 |
4.8 |
Overall yearly GDP growth |
6.5 |
5 |
Source:
Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation (May 31,
2013)
POVERTY INCREASES
ALONG WITH GROWTH
The
abysmal rate of
manufacturing growth is particularly noteworthy here. In
fact, since the
industrial recession of the mid-sixties which constituted a
crisis of the dirigiste
regime and a turning point for
the Indian economy, the country has never experienced two
successive years with
such abysmal industrial growth. This acute recession gets
somewhat camouflaged
by the service sector, but it is no less in its intensity
than what was
experienced in the mid-sixties, with one important
difference: the mid-sixties
recession was related to a sharp absolute drop in
agricultural, especially
foodgrain, output; the current recession is occurring even
in the absence of
any such drop.
A
point needs to be
clarified here. The Left has been arguing that even during
the years the
economy was experiencing high GDP growth rates, absolute
poverty, as measured
by the calorie norms specified by none other than the
Planning Commission
itself, has been increasing. From this fact an inference may
be drawn that if
high growth was associated with growing poverty then low
growth should be
associated with falling poverty; but this
is completely erroneous.
The
reason that absolute
poverty increased even in the period of high growth is
because this growth was
accompanied by a process of primitive accumulation of
capital that distressed
and dispossessed vast masses of peasants, fishermen,
agricultural labourers,
craftsmen, artisans and others, without
at the same time creating much proper employment
(other than “informal
employment,” “casual employment,” “part-time employment”
etc, which are but a
camouflage for the reserve army of labour). The slowdown in
growth will lower
the growth rate of employment even further; indeed the
industrial recession
will cause retrenchment of workers. But it
will not stop or slow down the process of primitive
accumulation of capital one
little bit. Hence the growth in absolute poverty will
only intensify
because of the current growth slowdown.
Putting
it differently,
the reason why absolute poverty has been increasing even in
a period of high
growth has to do with the specific trajectory of growth,
viz. the neo-liberal trajectory.
Along this trajectory, absolute poverty increases even when
growth is high
(since a substantial increase in the pace of primitive
accumulation of capital
is an immanent feature of this entire trajectory); and it
increases even faster
when the pace of growth slows down because the pace of
proper employment
generation, already inadequate in the period of high growth,
becomes even more
so. It follows that the working people who had already been
victims of the
growth process earlier when the growth rate was high, will
become even greater
victims now when the growth rate slows down.
GOVT’S RESPONSE:
CREATION OF BUBBLES
The
response of the
government to the growth slump is instructive. Within the
neo-liberal
trajectory, where any substantial and leading role for
public investment is
eschewed, growth depends essentially upon what Keynes had
called the “animal
spirits” of the entrepreneurs which determine how much
investment they make. But
a very important characteristic of the capitalist market is
its incapacity to
distinguish between “speculators” and “entrepreneurs;” and
indeed in the era of
finance capital this distinction itself disappears since
even the so-called
“entrepreneurs” indulge in “speculation” as a matter of
course. The
intervention by the government therefore, which in any case
is confined to
stoking the “animal spirits” of the “entrepreneurs,”
necessarily also takes the
form of encouraging speculation; and this occurs typically
through the creation
of euphoric expectations in the form of “bubbles.” Thus,
almost the only weapon
used by the government for stimulating the economy within a
neo-liberal set-up
is the creation of asset-market bubbles.
This
is precisely what
Alan Greenspan, the chairman of the Federal Reserve Board in
the
Its
very effort, however,
is laying bare the cause of India’s high growth earlier,
which had to do with
the US “housing bubble”-led boom in the world economy on the
one hand, and a
domestic asset price bubble on the other (especially a stock
market bubble that
saw the Sensex zooming at one stage to reach 20,000 in
record time). Both these
bubbles have now collapsed, and with it the Indian
high-growth story; but the
Manmohan Singh government is still trying its best to
recreate the past. Opening
up new areas to foreign finance capital, opening up the
domestic multi-brand
retail to companies like the Walmart, trying to reach an
“amicable settlement”
on Vodafone’s tax evasion (which is a euphemism for letting
Vodafone get away
with it) so that foreign investors draw favourable
conclusions about India’s
“hospitality,” all these are meant to attract finance into
the economy so that
it can generate a new asset-price “bubble” (apart from
financing the burgeoning
current account deficit on the balance of payments).
The
Manmohan Singh
government, however, is making little headway. Indeed it can
only make little
headway, since the crisis in world capitalism leaves little
scope for entertaining
euphoric expectations about the Indian economy (given
especially its acute
current account deficit). Besides, the current recession in
Instead
of counteracting
the recession through an expansionary fiscal policy,
neo-liberalism demands
fiscal conservatism (the old pre-Keynesian policy of “sound
finance” that is
usually referred to these days as “fiscal consolidation”),
on the assumption
that it would start a new “bubble.” While this assumption
will not get realised
(it is not getting realised anywhere in the world), the
austerity enforced by
such a fiscal stance will only aggravate the recession. If
the present
neo-liberal regime continues then the crisis will only
intensify; and the
working people will have to suffer because of the caprices
of finance capital.