People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 17 April 28, 2013 |
Private Banks and Financial
Inclusion
C P Chandrasekhar
REFLECTING
its inherent bias, an early feature of neo-liberal reform
in
Around
11 banks were licensed based on the 1993 guidelines. The
experience with that
first post-reform effort at bringing in private banks to
expand and improve
banking services has shown the error of judgement involved
here. Many of the
successful cases – such as ICICI Bank, IDBI Bank and HDFC
Bank – drew their
strength from being offshoots of organisations that were
established and grew
during the pre-1991 regime. Many others – such as the
infamous Global Trust
Bank, Centurion Bank, UTI Bank and Times Bank – were
pushed into being closed
and/or taken over either by other private banks or public
sector banks. The
most controversial was Global Trust Bank, once the models
of
post-liberalisation banking which was found to have been
engaged in
circumventing regulation and was embroiled in the Ketan
Parekh stock market
scam. It had to be shut down and forced merged with the
public sector Oriental
Bank of Commerce.
CORPORATE ENTRY
INTO PRIVATE BANKING
Despite
this experience, the government has now decided to not
only to issues a second
round of licences for private banks but raise the limit on
voting rights of
individual shareholders and permit entry of corporate
houses into private
banking. In fact, this is being justified with the claim
that the move would
favour financial inclusion. A respected former deputy
governor of the Reserve
Bank of
The
argument that private banks could contribute to quickly
resolving this problem
is based on a number of arguments. The first is that
inclusion is promoted by
augmenting the number of banks, since competition would
drive players to
under-banked and unbanked areas. The second is that since
large corporate
houses have rural reach and deep pockets, they would
stretch themselves to tap
this large market where per capita income has crossed some
critical threshold.
The third is that the guidelines for those seeking
licences to establish
private banks have made clear that they have to meet
financial inclusion
requirements. Assuming there is much profit to be made
from banking in areas
conventionally targeted by private banks, the latter are
expected to meet the
inclusion requirement to get a hand in the till.
The
problem is that past experience provides conclusive
evidence that private,
especially corporate players do not behave the way these
arguments expect them
to. Financial inclusion involves ensuring that (i) the
reach of banking is
geographically widespread; (ii) the banking sector is
successful in mobilising
an adequate and rising volume of deposits and use it as
the base for expanding
credit availability; and (iii) the allocation of credit is
not sectorally
skewed, with adequate flow to agriculture and the
small-scale sector.
The
heyday of corporate presence in banking was the period
spanning from 1947 to
bank nationalisation in 1969, when the skew in India’s
banking development
under the British in favour of the colonial government and
British business at
the expense of Indian capital was corrected and the
banking sector came under
the control of Indian business, excepting for the State
Bank of India and its
subsidiaries. Immediately after India won independence,
the Imperial Bank of
India that was subsequently nationalised to create the SBI
accounted for close
to a quarter of the deposits of the formal banking system.
The co-operative
banks accounted for another 6.5 per cent, leaving the rest
with the private
banks, domestic and foreign. This was followed by a period
when the failure of
a number of unviable banks that had come up in the
inter-War period and during
the Second World War failed or were amalgamated with
others, resulting in a
substantial reduction in the number of banks from 566 in
1951 to 210 in 1961
and 85 in 1969. Among the banks that remained were those
controlled by one or
other business group. Many of these banks featured among
the top 20 of that
time.
The
impact that this corporate control over banking had on the
business of banking
is well known. One was, of course, the skewed distribution
of credit across
sectors, with industry capturing an overwhelming share of
incremental credit. The
Dutt Committee found that in 1960, the top 20 private
sector banks accounted
for 61.7 per cent of all scheduled bank deposits and 73.2
per cent of scheduled
bank advances. Around 10 per cent of the aggregate
advances made by these banks
went to companies in which their directors had an
interest. In nominal terms,
bank credit rose from 547 crore in 1950-51 to Rs 3,396
crore in 1968-69. During
this period, the share of scheduled bank advances going to
industry rose from
33.6 at the end of 1950-51 to 52.7 per
cent at the end of 1961 and as much as 61.5 per cent in
March 1965. On the
other hand, the share of agriculture fell from 2.1 per
cent, to 0.4 per cent
and a negligible 0.2 per cent in those three years, when
the share of
agriculture and allied sectors in GDP stood at 52, 48 and
44 per cent
respectively. There could not be more stark evidence of
exclusion.
Further,
most Indians did not have access to banking facilities at
all. The population
per branch in the country was at a high of 87,000 in 1951
and rose to as much
as 98,000 in 1958 (because of closures of banks), before
coming down to 88,000
in 1964 and 64,000 in 1969. Even this was huge when
compared to the figure of around
6500 for the
A
corollary of this was the lack of any correspondence
between the geographical
distribution of bank branches and the population. At the
end of the 1960s, when
around 80 per cent of
After
the nationalisation of 14 large commercial banks in 1969,
things changed
dramatically. There was a huge expansion in banking, with
the population per
branch falling from 37,000 at the end of 1972 to 18,000 at
the end of 1981 and
14,000 by March 1991. Partly as a result of the creation
of the category and
the establishment of regional rural banks, the number of
scheduled commercial
banks rose from 74 in 1972 to 270 in 1990. The share of
rural branches in total
scheduled commercial bank branches rose in tandem from 22
per cent in 1969 to
58 per cent in 1990. The share of agricultural credit in
total non-food credit also
rose sharply from 2 per cent before nationalisation to 8.5
per cent in 1970-71
and close to 21 per cent in the mid 1980s, before falling
to 17 per cent by the
end of the 1980s. Small scale and other priority sector
advances also rose,
resulting in the increase in the share of priority sector
advances in total
credit from 22 per cent in 1972 to as much as 45 per cent
at the end of 1980s.
In sum, public ownership, the end of corporate control
over banks and the turn to
social control over banking resulted in dramatic progress
in the direction of
social inclusion.
IMPORTANCE OF
SOCIAL BANKING
The
importance of the end of corporate control and turn to
social banking comes
through when we examine developments in the period after
1991, when financial
liberalisation was begun, social control diluted and
foreign and domestic
private banks (though not corporate entities) were
permitted to enter. The
number of scheduled commercial banks that rose from 270 in
1990 to 302 in 1999
has since declined to 165 in 2011 as banks were closed on
grounds of
non-viability. The axe fell more heavily on branches in
rural areas, resulting
in a decline in the share of rural branches in the total
from 58 per cent in
1990 to 37 per cent in 2011. The population per bank
branch rose from 13,700 in
1991 to 15,200 in 2001 and close to 16,000 by the end of
the first decade of
this century.
The
impact of the turn to private initiative and away form
social banking
principles was visible also in a decline in the share of
priority sector
advances in total non-food credit, from 40 per cent in
1990 to 33 per cent in
2012. The figures for the shares of agriculture and the
small-scale industrial
sector were 16.4 and 15.4 in 1990 and 12.2 and 6 per cent
in 2012 respectively .
Thus
the changes prior to and after 1969 and prior to and after
1990 establish quite
clearly that corporate exclusion, public ownership and
social control are
crucial for financial exclusion, and the dilution of
public control aggravates
exclusion. These trends question the arguments advanced by
the advocates of
corporate entry into banking. This is to be expected.
Financial inclusion
requires providing access to services and credit to a
large number of highly
dispersed and often remotely located individuals and
agents. This raises
transaction costs considerably, which if passed on to
clients in the form of
higher interest rates would price them out of the market.
So the returns from
inclusive banking tend to be much lower and occasionally
negative. This is also
true of inclusive sectoral lending since the interest
charged to borrowers for
productive purposes in the agricultural and small
industrial sector must be
“reasonable” when compared with the returns that can be
earned in those
sectors.
Public
sector banks often meet these requirements, even when
provided some interest
cost subvention by the government, by resorting to
cross-subsidisation – using
high returns in some areas to balance for low returns or
even small losses in
others. That of course means that even if profits are
positive, they are much
lower than what would be earned if financial inclusion was
not an objective. To
expect private banks to settle for this lower profit
margin and rate, is to
forget the nature of private incentive. It is only by
presuming that private
operators will not behave like private operators and have
changed character
since the 1950s and 1960s that the entry of the corporate
sector into banking be
seen as an instrument to advance financial inclusion.
Evidence from elsewhere
in the economy shows there are no grounds for that
presumption.