People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVII
No. 11 March 17, 2013 |
Neo-Liberalism Has
Run Its Course
Prabhat Patnaik
NEO-LIBERALISM
was
always anti-people; it entailed the use of the State for the
exclusive
promotion of the interests of international finance capital,
with which the
domestic big bourgeoisie was aligned, at the expense of the
people. Even during
that phase of neo-liberalism in India when the country was
supposed to have
been “shining”, by having an unprecedented rate of GDP
growth that entitled it
to the status of an “emerging economic superpower”, there
was an increase, not
just in absolute terms but even relative to the population
as a whole, in the extent
of hunger and poverty.
Poverty is
defined
in
INCREASING
DISPOSSESSION
The fact
that
higher GDP growth has been accompanied by growing absolute
poverty should not
cause any surprise. This period of high growth has witnessed
a process of
dispossession of petty producers, peasants, petty traders,
artisans, and
craftsmen, and hence also a displacement of those employed
by them (such as
agricultural labourers), without any
corresponding expansion of the active army of labour
employed in the capitalist
(and State) sectors. The annual growth rate in “usual
status” employment
according to the National Sample Survey between 2004-5 and
2009-10, for
instance, was a mere 0.8 per cent per annum, which, let
alone absorbing those
dispossessed by the on-going process of “primitive
accumulation of capital”,
was way below the growth rate of the work-force itself.
Those dispossessed
therefore simply added to the ranks of the “reserve army of
labour”, appearing
in official statistics as “informal sector employees” or
“casual employees” or
“self-employed workers” earning a pittance. Not only did the
real incomes of
this vast segment of the population decline as a
consequence, but the real wage
rates of the organised sector workers too were kept down by
this growing
reserve army of labour, through a reduction in their
bargaining strength
vis-a-vis capital. All this contributed to an increase in
absolute poverty. Besides,
even when the petty producers, peasants and petty traders
were not actually
dispossessed of their assets, but lingered on instead in
their traditional
occupations, they did so at much lower levels of real income
than before, which
also meant an increase in absolute poverty.
The fact
that
neo-liberalism, even
at its most
“successful”, has still entailed an increase in the
extent of absolute
immiserisation, implies that it is historically
obsolete, that it necessarily constitutes only a passing
phase in an epoch when
the people have been historically on the move to control
their own destiny. But
Lenin once drew a significant distinction between a
phenomenon being “historically
obsolete” and its being “practically obsolete”.
Neo-liberalism,
even though historically obsolete could in principle still
linger on for years
before it became “practically obsolete”; but, as a
consequence of the world
capitalist crisis, it has now become even “practically
obsolete” in countries
like ours; it has run
its course.
The
neo-liberal
growth phenomenon in
Both these
bubbles
have now collapsed, and there are little prospects of any
new bubbles appearing
in the foreseeable future. Since under the neo-liberal
dispensation, the
formation of bubbles is the main basis for growth (as
Keynesian-style State
spending is eschewed under this dispensation and “austerity”
apotheosised),
what this means is that the world economy will continue to
remain submerged in
crisis in the foreseeable future (with at best fitful
“recoveries”); and so
will the Indian economy as long as it is straitjacketed by a
neo-liberal
regime. This is already evident in the fact that industrial
growth in
This
slowing down
of growth, visible also in the GDP figures, may raise the
question: if the
earlier growth acceleration had been accompanied by an
increase in the percentage
of the absolutely poor, shouldn’t the slowing down in growth
have the opposite
effect of decreasing this percentage? Should we not be
welcoming this
deceleration as being in the interests of the people? The
answer is an obvious
“no”, because the effects of acceleration and a deceleration
in growth rates of
GDP are not synonymous.
The
dispossession
of petty producers, and the income loss suffered by them and
by the labourers
employed by them, is not a reversible process. What is more,
this process of
“primitive accumulation of capital” will not come to an end
as a consequence of
the slow-down in growth; on the contrary, for reasons we
shall discuss shortly,
its tempo is likely to be accelerated. The slowdown in
growth therefore, while
not effecting any amelioration in the condition of the
people, and indeed
worsening it through a further reduction in the meagre
growth of the active
army of labour that had been occurring, will additionally
bring even the urban
educated middle class youth, which had witnessed some
increase in employment
opportunities till now, into the fold of the sufferers.
But it is
not just
the growth slowdown that expresses the “practical
obsolescence” of
neo-liberalism. The economic crisis of the capitalist world
has resulted inter
alia in a massive widening of
OBVIOUS
ADVERSITY
Under
neo-liberalism, which eschews import controls or even any significant
increase in tariffs, there is no
easy way of closing this deficit, and the recent budget
detailed no attempts at
doing so. The government is reportedly planning to raise
export subsidies, in
the form of duty drawbacks to the tune of Rs10,000 crores
per annum, to boost
exports; but even government officials admit that this would
only put some
extra money in the pockets of exporters, who would resort in
addition to
over-invoicing of exports, rather than actually earning more
foreign exchange
for the country. Indeed the government’s concern has been
more with financing
the deficit than with closing
the deficit, in the hope, which
is without any basis, that the revival of the world economy
will occur soon and
cure the deficit problem automatically. And for financing
this deficit, the
government’s thrust has been to draw foreign capital flows.
The recent
budget accordingly
was aimed essentially at the financial markets, to maintain
a good credit
rating for
The
contradiction
here is the following: the measures for financing
the deficit are precisely the ones that preclude a closing of the deficit, or any solution
to the basic problem of the deficit. Financing the
deficit within a
neo-liberal regime requires wooing international finance
capital so that it can
flow in adequate quantities; this requires an even stricter
adherence to the
tenets of neo-liberalism: controlling the fiscal deficit and
avoiding any
additional taxation of the rich, both of which inevitably
lead to expenditure
cuts; and effecting
still freer
cross-border flows of commodities and capital. Such
freer flows however not
only prevent any closure of the payments deficit but also
make the economy
vulnerable to capital flight
in the
event of inflows being
inadequate
over some stretch of time and thereby setting off fears of a
currency
depreciation. In other words, if adequate capital in any
period does not flow
in, then this very fact will cause
substantial capital to flow out.
True, India has accumulated large foreign exchange reserves,
which it may be
thought, can be used to prevent such a dire predicament; but
these reserves,
built out of financial inflows in the past rather than any
current account
surplus as in the case of China, are such that any
significant depletion in
them would create expectations of a currency depreciation
and stimulate capital
flight.
Neo-liberalism
has
thus brought the country to the brink of a precipice; and
even the belief that
it would not topple over this precipice rests on the hope of
a revival of the
world economy which is far-fetched. The twelfth five-year
plan document itself defines
the “normal comfort level” of the current account deficit as
2.5 per cent of
the GDP, beyond which there is a risk of non-availability of
external finance. It
can be imagined therefore how utterly unrealistic it is to
rely on such inflows
to finance a current deficit in excess of 5 per cent of the
GDP!
The people
will be
squeezed in the very attempt to attract financial inflows,
both because of
government expenditure cuts, and also because of the push
for further
neo-liberal measures (of which FDI in multi-brand retail,
permitting foreign
banks and moves to privatise postal services are obvious
examples). And they
would be squeezed even further, and to an immeasurable
degree, if finance does
not come in despite such blandishments, for in such a case a
financial crisis
will be precipitated leading to a further fall in the rupee,
which would
accentuate inflation, and a desperate plea for an IMF
bail-out, which would
bring draconian “austerity” in its train.
The
pursuit of
neo-liberal policies in a period of word capitalist crisis
is fraught with
obvious adversity. But the government of the big bourgeoisie
has no alternative
course to follow. It is for the working class and its
political formations to
provide the leadership for a transition to an alternative
economic trajectory.