People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No. 42 October 21, 2012 |
Prabhat Patnaik
DURING the first
decade of this
century when both
One may be critical
of China’s
economic policies, notwithstanding their success in ushering
in high growth,
for a variety of reasons, but it is undeniable that China’s
economy is on an
altogether different footing today than India’s, a fact that
was somewhat
camouflaged earlier when the world capitalist economy itself
was doing well. An
important corollary which follows is that those who defend
neo-liberal policies
in
CRUCIAL
DIFFERENCE
Two aspects of this
difference are
relevant here. The first is that
The total employment generated per unit value of
exports, both direct
and indirect, when these exports consist of manufactured goods
is therefore
larger in the domestic economy than the total employment
generated per unit
value of exports when these consist of IT-related services.
The impact of a
unit value of exports in alleviating unemployment and using up
labour reserves,
which lie at the root of poverty in economies like ours, is
therefore larger
when these exports consist of manufactured goods as in
In addition, for the
reason already
mentioned, viz the higher import-intensity of the expenditure
of the relatively
better-paid service sector employees, more imports are
demanded per unit value
of exports from this sector than per unit value of exports of
manufactured
goods (a proposition that would be true even after taking
account of imported
inputs of the manufacturing sector when the manufactured goods
are of the
relatively simple kind, as in the case of China). Hence the
balance of payments
effects of export growth when this growth is of exports such
as
ANOTHER BASIC
DIFFERENCE
Consider a country
whose exports are
100 and imports, for a
particular level
of domestic economic activity, are 50. If world demand
falls because of a
crisis, and its exports fall to, say, 80, then it can still maintain its level of domestic activity
without any
balance of payments difficulties; all that would happen
is that its trade
surplus, instead of being 50 as was the case earlier would now
shrink to 30.
True, the decline in exports from 100 to 80 would mean reduced
aggregate
demand, especially demand for those goods that were being
exported earlier; but
this deficiency in demand can be made up by increasing its
fiscal deficit by
20. The world economy’s crisis in other words would not affect
such a country:
it can maintain its output and employment by expanding its
fiscal deficit to
offset the decline in world demand for its goods, and can do
so with impunity
because its balance of payments current account, already in
surplus to start
with, would not get into the red anyway (unless the decline in
world demand for
its goods exceeds its initial current account surplus).
Now, consider the
case of another
country which has a current deficit to start with, at some
particular level of
domestic economic activity. Suppose its exports are 100 and
its imports are 130
and its gets foreign capital inflows of 50 which pay for its
current account
deficit and add 20 to its reserves. Now, suppose its exports
fall to 80, ie, by
20 as in the previous example, because of the world crisis;
then its current
account deficit increases to 50 and it cannot do without
getting the same
amount 50 of capital inflows as before, even when it does not
add to its
reserves. Any lower amount of capital inflows would mean a
depletion of its
reserves, which of course cannot continue for long; besides,
such a depletion,
if it sets off a capital flight by speculators, can make the
reserves disappear
overnight. If the decline in exports compared to the initial
situation is
larger than the accretion to reserves in the initial
situation, then the amount
of capital inflows needed to maintain the same level of output
and employment
as in the initial situation, will be even larger than initial
situation.
MOUNTING
ATTACKS
To maintain, or even
expand, the
inflow of capital, in the changed situation when everybody,
including the
financial speculators, know that the country’s balance of
payments situation
has become precarious, the country will have to undertake
massive measures to
entice global finance capital into its shores; and every single one of these measures would be
aimed at squeezing the
people, for that is precisely what boosts the “confidence of
investors” in the
economy. Thus, reducing subsidies to the people, raising
administered
prices, privatising public sector assets, cutting down on
welfare expenditure,
making the State retreat from the responsibility of providing
the essential
services needed by the people, increasing the burden of
indirect taxes to close
the fiscal deficit, are the typical measures that have to be
undertaken by the
State to entice finance capital.
But it is not as if
these measures,
once undertaken, will suffice for ever in enticing an annual
flow of finance
capital of the requisite order of magnitude to meet the
current account
deficit. The enticing effect of any particular set of measures
wears off after
some time, and a whole new set of measures have to be
announced in addition to
what has been already done. Like a drug addict needing
repeated doses of drugs
to keep himself going, finance capital requires repeated
announcements of
pro-finance and anti-people measures to come to a particular
country, and since
each set of measures is anti-people, their cumulative effect
against the people
builds up over time. To keep up the level of activity of the
country in this
second case therefore, there has to be a cumulative attack on
the people to entice
the flow of finance capital into the country. Besides, since
there is no
guarantee that finance would still come in to an appropriate
extent if such
measures are announced,
and since
finance itself generally wants “austerity” policies that lower
the level of
activity, such an economy typically ends up with a combination
of both lower levels of
activity (which in
effect means, once we move out of our simple example, lower
growth rates), and
cumulatively mounting attacks on the
living conditions of the people.
The contrast between
the two examples
given above is the contrast between
True, if the world
capitalist crisis
was just a passing event, so that the export drop was merely
temporary, and the
desperation associated with the need to attract global finance
within the
context of “liberalised” economy was a merely transitory
affair, then matters
might not have been as serious. But the world capitalist
crisis, far from being
a passing phase, is turning out, for good reasons, to be a
protracted one.
“Liberalised” economies like
China does not face
such dire
prospects, which is why those who are inspired by China’s
export and growth
successes to endorse “liberalisation”, who cite the Chinese
experience as
exemplifying the fate of a “liberalised” third world economy,
are so completely
off the mark.