People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No. 37 September 16, 2012 |
The
Other Half of Coal Loot: Through Power Market Prabir
Purkayastha THERE is a story doing the rounds: when a
minister
went up to Manmohan Singh complaining about “primitive
accumulation of capital”
with respect to a huge real estate scam, the PM asked
him what was wrong with
primitive accumulation, apart from the word primitive.
FREE
REIGN TO “ANIMAL
SPIRITS” This is the crux of the policies the
Manmohan Singh government has followed – give free
reign to the “animal
spirits” of Indian capital through loot of the
country’s natural resources. The
coal scam was fundamentally about transferring the
country’s huge coal reserves
to domestic capital at zero cost. And it was not only
about friends and
relations – the list also contains Reliance, TATA,
Hindalco (Birla), Vedanta,
Essar: virtually a list of all the top industrial
houses in the country. Just to give an indication of the
magnitude
of the loot – the government transferred about 44
billion metric tonnes of coal
to private capital gratis, about 6-7 times
the total annual production of the world! The
boom of Indian capital was on
the back of such transfers – whether KG Basin gas, 2G
spectrum or giving away
coal blocks. The argument the PM gave in parliament in
replying against the charges was two-fold. One was
that while he conceded that
there was a loss to the national exchequer by such
transfers, he decided to
nit-pick on the actual amount of loss calculated by
the CAG, “....even if we
accept CAG's contention that benefits accrued to
private companies, their
computations can be questioned on a number of
technical points.” The second was
the argument that the power sector would have suffered
greatly if coal blocks
had not been allocated to power companies. In any case
electricity rates are
regulated, so where is the loss? This is also the same argument that
Ministry of Power advanced to the CAG – that there was
indeed no loss as the
electricity rates are regulated by taking into account
the cost price of coal.
Therefore a lower price of coal would have translated
into a lower price of
electricity to consumers. Therefore, there was no
loss. The fact is that after passing of the
Electricity Act 2003 – passed by the NDA government
with Congress support – there is an
electricity market in the
country and private power companies have been selling
their power in
electricity market at unregulated rates.
Not only that, the UPA government has been promoting
the concept of merchant
power and an open market for power right from the
beginning and it still
remains the corner stone of its electricity policies.
Therefore the zero loss
argument given by the PM, Ministry of Power and Kapil
Sibal – that the benefit
of free coal was passed on to the consumers through
low cost power – is nothing
but a lie. SEQUENCE
OF
EVENTS Let us look at the sequence of events in
the electricity sector in conjunction with the coal
block allocation policy. In
2003, the Electricity Act is passed that mandates
removal of cross subsidies
and creating an open market for power. This is a
crucial step and is very much
the companion policy of coal allocation. Without a
power market, the companies
benefiting from coal blocks would only have realised a
part of the profits; a
real killing required that there be a power market as
well for selling their
low cost electricity in the open market. By the way,
the CAG has not computed
this extra killing that the power companies have made
by selling their power in
the open market. To make such a power market possible, it
is
necessary to “unbundle” the electricity sector –
separate generation,
transmission and distributions. A number of State
Electricity Boards (SEBs)
opposed such unbundling. The UPA government applied
the carrot and the stick –
all central transfers through Accelerated Power
Development Programme (APDRP),
location of Ultra Mega Power projects in the state,
etc would take place only
if the SEBs were unbundled. The World Bank and Asian
Development Bank also
stepped in with their soft loans for helping
“Electricity Sector Reforms” (read:
unbundling of the sector). The net result was that
most states buckled under
pressure and did unbundle their electricity boards. Once the SEBs were unbundled, we enter
Round
2 of the neo-liberal policies. Private power, which
till then was not very
enthusiastic, now finds investments in electricity
generation quite attractive.
They were being given free coal and now there is an
electricity market being
created for selling their power bypassing the
regulated route. This is the time
we see a huge investment in private power, eyeing what
is called the merchant
power route. Merchant power means selling the
electricity generated in plants not through long term
Power Purchase Agreements
(PPAs) but in the open market for power. Two power
exchanges, similar to the
stock exchanges – IEX
(Indian Energy Exchange) and PXI
(Power Exchange of India) – are also set up for this
purpose. The
National Electricity Policy 2005 formulated by the UPA
states, “To promote
market development, 15 per cent of the new generating
capacities, be sold
outside long term PPAs.” This is repeated in Ministry
of Power’s Merchant Power
Policy of adding 15,000 MW capacity by 2011-12. Even
National Thermal Power
Corporation was allowed to sell a part of its power
through the merchant power
route. So here is the scenario. Right from the
beginning, allocation of coal blocks has been
accompanied by a complementary
policy of creating a market for electricity and
allowing private generators to
sell their power through the merchant power route.
While the state owned
utilities would obviously have to sell their power to
the state owned
distribution utilities, the private companies would be
allowed to sell a part
of their power output in the open market. As the power
market would grow, a
much larger part of their output would be sold through
the power exchanges. THE
PUSH BEHIND OPEN
ACCESS POLICY This is the push behind what is called
open
access; all companies who own the wires – transmission
and distribution
companies –must allow their wires to be opened for
buyers and sellers of
electricity, irrespective of their locations. This is
the vision of the
Electricity Act 2003. If this has not happened, it is no fault
of
the central government. The states have resisted this
open access policy, as it
simply means a much larger loss for their distribution
companies. It would mean
that big buyers would desert the existing long term
contracts and rates fixed
by the regulators and buy from the open market. The
bulk of the low tariff
consumers – those who consume say less than 100 units
per month and the
agricultural sector – would remain with the state
distribution companies. Net result
would be higher charges for them and an even bigger
loss for the state owned
distribution companies. When we look at the losses of the
utilities, we find that with the neo-liberal reforms,
the subsidies provided by
the state as well as the losses have actually
increased dramatically. The
losses to the state owned power utilities in 1992-1993
were of the order of Rs
3,275 crore (Planning Commission, Annual Report on The
Working of State
Electricity Boards & Electricity Departments
2002). With 10 year of
reforms, it had increased to Rs 24,837 crore or by
about eight times. Today,
the accumulated losses of the power sector
distribution utilities stand at
about Rs 200,000 crore (Crisil Press Release, May 7,
2012), with three fourths
of these losses occurring in the last five years. Even
though with the unbundling
of the power sector, the losses of the sector have
increased dramatically and
the power sector is in deep financial crisis, the
pressure of privatisation and
more such market ‘reforms’ is actually increasing. Why have the losses of the state
distribution
companies increased by such leap and bounds in the
last five years? The answer
lies in the power market being created and that during
shortages, the
distribution companies are being forced to buy
electricity from market. It is
the high rate of such short term purchases that is
adding to the huge losses of
the distribution companies. How much electricity is being sold in the
power market? Today, about 12 per cent of the
electricity being produced is
being sold through the existing power markets. About
50 per cent are sold
through the power exchanges and what is called the
Unscheduled Interchange (UI)
mechanism, while another 50 per cent is sold through
the power trading
companies. And the average rate of electricity –
depending on the time of the
year – can range from as much as Rs 12 to Rs 4.50. Looking at the runaway prices in the
electricity market, the Central Electricity Regulator
had proposed a cap of Rs
8.00 in 2009 in the short-term market. This was at a
time when the cost of
production of the new power plants was about Rs 2.20
or thereabouts. Even
today, the average price of power in the short term
market is about twice the
cost of production of power. When the 2003 Electricity Act was being
passed, the Left parties, the unions and power experts
had commented that if
there is a scarcity in a market, competition will not
work. If supply is less
than demand, and if there are power shortages –and
this is indeed the case –
competition would only help to push up prices. What we
get is a competition between
buyers to buy a commodity of which there is not
enough. If people do not get
power, they will take to the streets and force the
governments to intervene and
buy power, whatever the rates. This is what happened
in When we look at the top private traders
in
the short term power market, the picture becomes even
clearer about who are the
beneficiaries of the coal scam. The top companies are
Jindal, Adani and Lanco,
also the major beneficiaries of the coal allocation. Of course, there are a whole bunch of
other
beneficiaries as well. TATAS and Reliance are not only
producers but also
distributors, serving urban areas where the rates are
relatively high. So is
CESC. They therefore do not need to sell in the short
term market but can sell
directly to their distribution companies. Also, coal
mines have been given to stock
market operators like India Bulls, new “players” like
Jaysawals, Abhijeet group,
etc, with no prior experience of either power
generation or handling coal
mines. A number of them have repeated the story of 2G
– have got the allocation
of the mines, floated shares of the companies and sold
them at a huge premium
based on their coal mines. This is what Sibal calls
the “normal” business. We have to agree that normal business of
capital is loot – and this is what the coal
allocations and the power market clearly
bring out – looting of natural resources through
selective allocation and a
power market to loot the consumers.