People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No. 35 September 02, 2012 |
The Allocation of Coal Blocks
Prabhat Patnaik
THE allocation of
captive coal blocks to private parties raises a number of
issues, of which only one, namely the loss to the exchequer,
because the allocation was not determined through auctions, has
received attention. Let us first discuss this issue itself,
before coming to others that have been ignored.
The fact that there has
been such a loss is so obvious that the Congress Party’s denial
of it can only be construed as an insult to the people’s
intelligence. The idea behind allocating captive coal blocks to
private parties is to assure them of coal supplies. They would
otherwise have had to buy the coal they need from, say, Coal
India Limited, at the latter’s sale price; instead they now
produce their own coal from the captive blocks given to them. If
the cost of production per unit of coal is less than this sale
price at which they would have got the coal otherwise, then the
profits that would have accrued to Coal
Since the estimate of
the loss can only be made with reference to a hypothetical
alternative scenario, with which the actual scenario must be
compared (in the above example, buying coal from CIL in the
absence of having captive blocks), there will always be some
difference of opinion on the exact magnitude of loss. But this
does not mean an absence of loss. Just as the fact that there
could be a difference of opinion about the magnitude of the
“drain of wealth” in colonial times from India to Britain, does
not negate the reality of the “drain”, likewise quibbles over
the estimated magnitude of loss cannot obscure the reality of
the loss to the exchequer.
RED
HERRINGS
Manmohan Singh’s
statement to the parliament, while careful not to claim “zero
loss”, simply introduced a lot of red herrings: its aim was to
obfuscate the issue and throw mud at the CAG’s report. But his
arguments were utterly specious. He claimed, for instance, that
the CAG had not taken into account the 26 per cent tax on
profits that the captive coal block owners would be paying on
mining profits, for local area development, under the Mining and
Minerals Development and Regulation Bill, that is currently with
the parliament. But this argument is flawed for many reasons:
one, the MMDR bill is still a pie in the sky and the CAG cannot
be faulted for not taking it into account; two, even if 26 per
cent of mining profits are taxed away, the logic behind making
captive coal blocks available to private parties makes sense
only in the absence of any profit-making whatsoever on their
part. If private firms make any profits at all on the captive
blocks, then that is an unwarranted bonanza for them, and hence
ipso facto a loss to
the exchequer. Put differently, all profits on mining on
captive blocks should be taxed away and not just 26 per cent
of profits, and if they are not, then that is a loss to
the exchequer. Three, in the case of captive coal blocks,
identifying the profits on coal production per se becomes
difficult, because the possibility of resorting to something
akin to “transfer pricing” opens up: because of intra-firm
sales, profits made on coal can be shown under some other
operation. Obtaining 26 per cent of coal profits for the
exchequer, therefore, becomes that much more difficult. And,
four, the fact that Manmohan Singh at all mentioned the 26 per
cent proposed taxation, implies that he was objecting to the
magnitude of the estimated loss, not to the fact of loss itself.
But he was not straight enough to admit the fact of loss.
Not only has there been
a loss to the exchequer from the allocation of coal blocks, but
this loss, it is equally obvious, could have been brought down
if the allocation had been based on auctions. The price of any
asset depends upon the expected stream of earnings from it that
its possession is supposed to yield. In fact, in the absence of
speculation, the price of an asset equals the sum of this stream
of earnings discounted at an appropriate rate of interest. If
there are any profits at all that the possession of captive coal
blocks ensures (and we know that it does), then the auction
price must be positive, which means that the revenue loss
entailed in giving away the captive blocks free would have been
recouped if the blocks had been auctioned.
PROBLEMS OF
AUCTION ROUTE
But it is a mistake to think
that the loss to the exchequer would have been fully recouped
if the blocks had been auctioned. The auction price
depends upon the expectations
of those participating in the auction about the future
stream of earnings. Up to 2004, coal prices were in the range of
$25-30 per tonne while the CIL’s cost of production was around
$30 per tonne. CIL was, in fact, making huge losses in this
period. But after 2004, there was an upsurge in coal prices,
because inter alia of
the surge in
The auction route, it
follows, is of course far preferable to merely handing over
captive coal blocks to a few select private parties; but the auction route does
not recoup the entire loss to the exchequer on account of
handing coal blocks to the private sector. This is because
the auction price depends upon the expected stream of
profits, while the loss to the exchequer depends upon the actual stream of
profits. And in a situation where the latter is greater
than the former, the actual loss to the exchequer exceeds what
the auction price can recoup.
CRUX OF
THE ISSUE
And this brings us to
the crux of the issue. We have to distinguish here between flows and stocks. Coal supplies
every year to the various private parties constitute a flow. The private
parties that need assured coal supplies really need flows of coal. But by
handing over coal blocks to them, the government is not just
assuring them of flows;
it is additionally giving them command over the entire reserves
of coal in those blocks, which constitute stocks. There is no
justification whatsoever for handing over stocks to private
parties whose needs (and let us assume that these needs are
legitimate) are only for flows.
Put differently, if the
government was keen that certain key coal users should have
assured supplies of coal, and that too, let us say, at assured
prices (though any such provision of an input like coal at
assured prices would make sense only when there is a
corresponding control over the prices of the final goods
produced by these key users), then it should have simply allowed
these users to enter into supply contracts with Coal India where
such assured supply quantities and prices were stipulated. This
would have meant that while the key users were assured of coal
supplies (and hence the objective that handing over captive coal
blocks to them is supposed to serve, would have been served),
the control over coal reserves would have remained with Coal
The government’s
retaining control over coal reserves would have enabled it to
determine how and at what rate these should be used, i.e. the
flow of output in any period. Handing over captive coal blocks
to key users implies ipso
facto that they would at best produce to meet their own
requirement, but would not produce in excess of it, even when
the country faces a coal shortage, as indeed it has been doing.
It amounts, in short, to an arrangement where coal production is
institutionally detached from catering to the scale of national
needs. In fact, as Manmohan Singh admitted in his statement
before parliament, several of the holders of captive coal blocks
have not been mining much coal. We have therefore had an absurd
situation where the country has been importing coal at
exorbitant prices, even as domestic production has been
languishing because reserves have been handed over to private
parties for captive use.
Handing over reserves,
whether they are actually mined or not in any
given period, is also a means of nurturing monopoly.
Capturing mineral reserves, as even Lenin had pointed out a
century ago, and thereby keeping potential rivals away from
access to those reserves, has always been a powerful instrument
for buttressing monopoly positions; and monopoly capitalists
often spend massive amounts for getting this privilege, even
when they do not actually use those reserves for long periods,
for it yields them monopoly profits on the final goods they
produce(which by the way is an additional reason for the coal
block auction price to be positive, i.e. positive even when
there are zero profits in coal production as such). In
LOSS TO
THE NATION
The problem in short
began not in 2004; it began in 1993 itself when the whole policy
of handing over captive coal blocks to private parties was
introduced. It was introduced in the name of assuring them of flows of coal supplies;
but it handed over to them stocks, i.e. reserves
of coal completely gratis.
The idea that coal should be developed within the public sector
was enshrined in the second industrial policy resolution of
1956, which in turn had claimed its lineage from the Directive
Principles of State Policy of the Indian Constitution. It was an
essential component of the Nehruvian policy and in keeping with
the elementary principle that control over exhaustible
resources, whose social use needs to be planned and carefully
calibrated, must vest with the State. The retreat from that
principle, the jettisoning of the vision enshrined in the second
industrial policy resolution, and the fraud on the constitution
that this entailed, whereby the nation’s precious resources were
simply handed over to
private parties in violation of the Directive Principles, came
with neo-liberalism itself in 1993.
Neo-liberalism however
constitutes a fraud not only on the constitution but upon its
own claims. It claims legitimacy in the name of ushering in
competition, ensuring a “level playing field” among
entrepreneurs. But it actually promotes, as we have seen,
monopoly of a few to the exclusion of others. In focusing on the
loss to the exchequer, we must not lose sight of this larger
loss to the nation.