People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No.
13 March 25, 2012 |
Budget
2012-13: The Return to Orthodoxy
Prabhat Patnaik
AFTER
the onset of the world capitalist crisis,
there was a brief period when most countries in the world attempted to
use the
State to stem the severity of the crisis, a period often described as
“the
Keynesian moment”. Some provided a very deliberate fiscal stimulus;
others
simply did not cut back on State expenditures even as State revenues
fell owing
to the recession, reducing thereby the intensity of the crisis.
AUSTERITY
AT
PEOPLE’S
EXPENSE
The
2012-13 budget represents a reversal of this
trend. Such a reversal indeed is evident all over the world, with “the
drive to
austerity” replacing the “Keynesian moment”. If the “Keynesian moment”
had
provided some barrier against the free fall of the world economy, the
return to
“austerity” at the expense of the people, which represents a
reassertion of the
hegemony of finance capital after a period of temporary shakiness, will
only
accentuate the global crisis.
This
reversal is evident from the very statement
of the objective of the budget, which is “fiscal consolidation”. The
point at
issue here is not whether the relative size of the fiscal deficit
should be reduced;
the point is how this reduction is to be effected. The Left too
is
opposed to a burgeoning fiscal deficit, but for a reason which is very
different from that of finance capital and which the bourgeois media
gloss
over. This reason is as follows.
Suppose
the State is to spend Rs 100. It can
finance this expenditure either by borrowing or by raising taxes. Let
us for
simplicity ignore for a moment all foreign borrowing and indeed foreign
transactions. Then borrowing this amount domestically does not involve,
as is
commonly supposed, drawing from some fixed, pre-existing pool (and
thereby
leaving less for others); it involves, on the contrary, generating
an
additional Rs 100 of savings in private hands over and above the
private
sector’s own investment. In other words what is borrowed is itself
put into
the hands of those (i.e. the capitalists) from whom it is borrowed.
Now,
savings constitute addition to wealth; borrowing-financed State
expenditure
therefore adds to the wealth of the private sector, i.e. of the
capitalists. If
what is borrowed would have been simply impounded from them through
taxation,
then this additional wealth would have been snatched away from them. Everything
else remaining unchanged, borrowing-financed State expenditure
therefore
entails a greater wealth inequality compared to the same State
expenditure
financed by direct taxes on the capitalists. The Left
opposes a
fiscal deficit for this reason; it always argues for curtailing
the
fiscal deficit and imposing direct taxes on the capitalists instead,
which has the same effect on employment as if the fiscal deficit were
not
curtailed, which does not squeeze the consumption of the poor, and
which at the
same time checks the increase in wealth inequalities.
This,
however, is not the way that spokesmen for
finance present the consequences of a fiscal deficit. They deliberately
use the
obfuscating term “fiscal consolidation”, which suggests that a
reduction in
fiscal deficit brought about not at the expense of the rich, but
just anyhow,
is preferable to no reduction. They thereby suggest that a fiscal
deficit is
always bad per se, and use this argument to justify “austerity”
at the
expense of the people. The view that a fiscal deficit is bad per se
(and
not because its effect on wealth inequalities is worse than if the same
expenditure would have been financed through taxing the capitalists),
was
called by Joan Robinson, the renowned Left Keynesian economist, the
“humbug of
finance”. The 2012-13 budget uses this “humbug” to launch a “drive to
austerity” at the expense of the people.
Ironically,
the Budget document itself (in its Key
Features) attributes the “deterioration” in the fiscal balance in
2011-12
to “slippages in direct tax revenue and increased subsidies”. Now,
increased
subsidies are inevitable in a period of inflation; but if there were
slippages
in direct tax revenue, then it obviously followed that the budget
should have
made an effort to undo these slippages by raising direct tax revenue.
Instead,
we find that total direct tax revenue is budgeted to increase by only
13.9 per
cent over 2011-12 (RE), while customs, excise and service tax revenues
together
are to increase by 26.7 per cent. In fact, the share of direct tax
revenue in
GDP is to marginally come down in 2012-13; the entire adjustment for
“fiscal
consolidation” is to occur through cuts in subsidies and relief
expenditures
and increases in indirect and service tax revenue. It is to be achieved
in
short, in the midst of inflation, by exacerbating inflation through
indirect
tax hikes, and cutting back on subsidies, i.e. by squeezing the people.
CONTRACTION
OF
FOOD
SECURITY
The
fact that the virtually unchanged food
subsidy bill (the increase in trivial, from Rs 73,000 crores to Rs 75,
000
crores), is rather like “the dog that did not bark”, and amounts to a
scuttling
of the much-awaited food security programme, has been noted by many.
But
looking at the food subsidy bill alone in this context is inadequate.
The
fertilizer subsidy bill is slated to come down from Rs 67,199 crores in
2011-12
(RE) to Rs 60, 974 crores in 2012-13, and the petroleum subsidy bill
from Rs
68, 481 crores to Rs 43,580 crores. This would certainly increase the
cost of
production for the farmers; and the increase will be particularly sharp
if the
world oil prices climb still higher, as seems likely. If the
procurement prices
offered to the peasants reflect this increase in cost of production,
then the
unchanged food subsidy bill will entail not just no expansion in the
scope of the
public distribution system, contrary to the objective of the food
security
programme, but an actual contraction, or alternatively a rise in issue
prices.
What the budget entails therefore is not just no expansion in the scope
of food
security, but an actual contraction.
Much
the same can be said about the MGNREGS,
where the reduction is from Rs 40,000 crores in last year’s budget to
Rs 33,
000 crores in the current year’s. Jairam Ramesh has justified this cut
on the
following grounds: expenditure in the current year on MGNREGS would be
only Rs
38,000 crores, compared to which the budgetary provision of Rs 33,000
crores
plus the carry-over balance with states of Rs 6,000 crores plus their
own
contribution of Rs 3,300 crores (together adding to Rs 42,300 crores)
is ample
increase. The problem however lies in the fact that basing MGNREGS
outlays on
past expenditure itself amounts to a scuttling of the programme. It is
rather
like saying that nothing need be done about ensuring dalit
entry into
temples because past records show not many dalits as having
entered
temples! MGNREGS, though nominally a rights-based programme, is far
from being
one in practice; and there is a whole array of vested interests that
are
opposed to its continuance. What is necessary therefore is increasing
outlays on it and forcing its implementation as a rights-based
programme;
while to cut down outlays on the grounds that they are not being used,
is a de
facto abandoning of it.
Thus
both the major schemes, MGNREGS and the
food security programme, which were supposed to provide neo-liberalism
with a
human face are being given a slow and quiet burial. It will, of course,
be
argued that social sector outlays have gone up in the current budget,
but the
increase in school education by 17 per cent entails only marginal
increase in
outlay relative to GDP. And the increase in health and family welfare
outlay by
22 per cent, though higher than the expected nominal GDP growth, will
still
keep central government’s health expenditure at an abysmal 0.3 per cent
of GDP!
We have in short a return with a vengeance to neo-liberal orthodoxy and
a
snuffing out of the “Left-inspired” (UPA-I) and the “Keynesian” moments.
This
fact is of great significance. There was a
time when neo-liberal policies were justified on the grounds that the
inequalities they generate would usher in high growth whose effects
would
eventually “trickle down” to the poor. The fact that this did not
happen then
produced another apologia: the high growth ushered in by the
inequalities engendered
by neo-liberalism would raise government resources which can then be
used for
the poor. The more savvy neo-liberal apologists these days use this
latter
argument. And for a while because of the specificity of the “moments”
mentioned
earlier, it appeared to many that the apologists might well have a
point. Such
however is not the case. The interests of finance capital and of the
corporate-financial elite that promotes neo-liberalism are opposed to
those of
the people. There is never any “trickle down”, neither an automatic nor
a
State-mediated one. The only way that the people’s interests can be
defended is
if there is fight for them, against the corporate-financial elite,
against the
hegemony of finance capital and the neo-liberal policies it promotes.
Government
spokesmen, at least those who do not
merely mouth platitudes, may defend the strategy of the budget on the
following
lines: with the world economy slowing down, India will face a major
current
account deficit if it maintains its growth rate; to finance this
deficit it
will be necessary to attract financial inflows for which a return to
orthodox
hard-nosed neo-liberalism, of the sort that enthuses international
finance
capital, becomes necessary. The strategy underlying the budget
therefore is the
only one that can achieve both high growth and balance of payments
equilibrium.
It
may appear at first sight that within the
logic of a neo-liberal regime these spokesmen may have a point. But
even
within this logic, the denouement is likely to be the
very opposite
of what they suggest. The return to neo-liberal orthodoxy has obviously
not
been up to the expectations of the corporate-financial elite, as shown
for
instance by the stock market’s response to the budget. It is quite
likely
therefore that even as the “drive to austerity” at the expense of the
people
brings down the growth rate, the balance of payments will get into a
crisis
because of the outflow of finance. Such outflow will
be even
greater if the anti-people thrust of the budget brings about widespread
popular
resistance which makes India a less than attractive destination for
globalised
finance. The budget would then have pushed the economy into the worst
of both
the worlds, in terms of growth and balance of payments, even while
attacking the
people, and indeed because of its very attack on the people.