People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXVI
No. 02 January 08, 2012 |
The Nature of the
Current Capitalist Crisis Prabhat Patnaik EVERYBODY
is agreed that
capitalism is undergoing a serious crisis, but different
people read this
crisis differently. The commonest view, held even by
progressive economists
like Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz, is that the
crisis is entirely a
consequence of the collapse of the housing “bubble;”
since in this situation of
crisis, private
expenditure, whether on
consumption or on investment, is unlikely to increase in
the foreseeable future;
a revival is possible only through an increase in state
expenditure, which
means that both in the United States and in Europe, far
from adopting austerity
measures, the state should instead be increasing its
expenditure. The fact that
this panacea for crisis is not being adopted is then
explained by the “bad
economics” of the opinion makers, the “bad faith” of the
Republicans, the
callousness of the Right, and so on. This view, in
short, sees the crisis
exclusively as an isolated, one-off phenomenon, a
predicament to which the US
economy and hence the world economy happens to have
fallen because of the
collapse of a “bubble”-based boom, which the earlier
irresponsible monetary
policy of the Federal Reserve Board under the
chairmanship of Alan Greenspan
had connived to stimulate. STRUCTURAL CRISIS The
problem with this view
is that it is extremely limited; it does not see the
whole truth. The crisis
caused by the collapse of the housing “bubble” is only a
part of the story; it
is itself located within a fundamental structural crisis
of capitalism. Indeed
the “dotcom” and housing “bubbles” had kept this
structural crisis hidden;
with their collapse we not only
have the crisis caused by this collapse itself, but its
superimposition upon
the basic structural crisis which now gets revealed as
well. Since this
structural crisis is embedded in the logic of the
capitalist system, what we
have is a systemic crisis, not a sporadic or a cyclical
one, from which there
is no easy way out. In short, we have entered a period
of protracted crisis of
capitalism, reminiscent of the 1930s, which will open up
not immediately but
through a whole chain of political developments that it
will unleash as in the
30s and the 40s, real revolutionary possibilities of
transcending the system. Let
us begin by asking the
question: why is there so much opposition to state
expenditure as a means of
overcoming the crisis both in the It is not opposed to
state activism as such, but it wants
that activism to take the form of providing incentives
to itself, of promoting
its own interests, as the means of reviving the
economy.
It does not want direct state
action for this purpose through larger public
expenditure. Any state action
that operates independently of finance capital, that
seeks to work directly
instead of working through the promotion of
corporate-financial interests,
undermines the social legitimacy of capitalism, and
especially of the
corporate-financial interests. For it raises the
question: if the state is
required to fix the system then why do we need the
system at all, why not have state
ownership itself? Finance capital in the US. therefore
has no objections to $13
trillion of state support for stabilising the financial
system; but the moment
the question of state expenditure for reviving the
economy is raised, it begins
to preach the virtues of “austerity.” The
era of hegemony of finance therefore is an era where
“state intervention in
demand management” a la Keynes
recedes to the background. Now,
capitalism always
requires some exogenous stimuli for sustaining its
growth. It can sustain
growth purely on its own steam, i.e. purely because
growth had been occurring,
for some time, but if growth peters out for any reason,
including the emergence
of bottlenecks because of growth itself, then an
opposite spiral of lower and
lower investment and declining growth sets in which
carries it towards a
stationary state, i.e. towards a state of simple
reproduction. Extricating the
system out of simple reproduction and ensuring that
growth does not lose steam
and collapse back into a state of simple reproduction is
something that is
ensured by the operation of a set of exogenous stimuli.
EXTERNAL STIMULI Historically,
two sets of
exogenous stimuli have played this role. The first is
the entire colonial
system that played this role right until the first world
war. The term
“colonial system” is used here not just to refer to
colonial and semi-colonial
possessions like India and China, but also to the
so-called “settler colonies”
from where the “native population” was driven away to
accommodate immigrants
from the capitalist core. The “colonial system” propped
up growth under
capitalism in the following manner: along with migration
of population to the
“settler colonies” or the temperate regions of white
settlement, there was also
a parallel migration of capital to these regions from
the capitalist core, but
this “export of capital” from the core was made possible
through an appropriation
of surplus from the colonial and semi-colonial
possessions. So the “drain” of
surplus without any quid pro quo from India and other
colonies financed the
capital exports from the capitalist core to the settler
colonies. But
underlying these movements
in “value” magnitudes there were also important changes
relating to commodity
composition: Britain, the leading capitalist country and
also the leading
capital-exporting country, did not produce goods which
were in high demand in
the settler colonies like the United States. The demand
there was substantially
for raw materials, i.e. minerals and primary
commodities, which were produced
in the colonial possessions. Hence Britain’s capital
exports were made possible
first by British goods like textiles being sold in the
Indian and other eastern
markets, and goods from the these latter countries being
exported to a
matching, or, where “drain” occurred, to an even
greater, extent from these
countries. British goods could be sold in the colonial
and semi-colonial
countries because they were markets on “tap”: their
markets could be used for
unloading British goods, to the extent required, any
time. This
entire pattern of
global movement of capital and commodities, which was
very convenient from the
point of view of the capitalist core, underlay the
prolonged boom that
capitalism witnessed from the mid-nineteenth century
until the first world war.
After the first world war, this pattern collapsed.
Domestic bourgeoisies in
colonies wanted their own space; Japan emerged as a
rival to Britain in Asian
markets; the scope for investment in the “new world” got
exhausted with the
“closing of the frontier;” and the scope for
further de-industrialisation in economies like
India also began to get
more and more limited. The Great Depression of the 1930s
was an expression of
the fact that the old mechanism for stimulating buoyancy
in capitalism could no
longer function. The
Depression ended only
when the second major exogenous stimulus for capitalism,
namely state
expenditure, came into effect, initially for war
preparations, and after the
war, under the impact of working class pressure and the
threat of socialism,
for introducing some “welfare state” measures. But
“state intervention in
demand management” has also now run its course: the
emergence of international
finance capital as the hegemonic force under capitalism
has, for reasons
mentioned earlier, has attenuated the scope for it. Capitalism, in short, now lacks any mechanism
for imparting sustained
growth to it. FALLING REAL WAGES This,
moreover, is
happening in a context when the need for such a
mechanism is becoming ever more
acute. Let us see why. With globalisation there has been
much freer flow of capital,
including in the form of finance, and also of goods and
services, across
countries than ever before in the history of capitalism.
As a result, capital
from the metropolis (and domestic big capital as well)
can locate production in
the third world countries, where wages are low because
of the existence of massive
labour reserves, and export to the metropolitan markets.
This in turn makes the
wages of workers in the metropolitan countries
vulnerable to the downward drag
exerted by the labour reserves existing in the third
world countries. In the
United States, for instance, in the last three decades
the real wage rate of
workers has fallen in absolute terms by nearly 30 per
cent. In
third world countries,
in turn, it is not as if the real wage rate increases;
on the contrary, the
immiserisation and displacement of petty producers,
including peasants, that is
another hallmark of globalisation, entails a swelling of
the reserve army of
labour which also exerts a downward drag on the real
wage rate of workers that
constitute the active army of labour for capitalism.
Taking the world economy
as a whole, therefore, there is a tendency for the real
wage rate of the
workers to decline, or at the very least, not to
increase. At the same time,
however, there is a steady rise in labour productivity,
which means that the
share of surplus value is total output increases. Now,
since a rupee of
output coming to the workers gives rise to a much larger
amount of consumption
that a rupee coming to the capitalists, any rise in the
share of surplus value
in output has, other things remaining the same, a
demand-depressing effect. If
capitalists’ investment increased when the extra rupee
came to them, then this
demand-depressing effect could be overcome, and the
entire produced output
could be realized. But, we have already seen that the
tendency for capitalists’
investment, far from rising, is to remain subdued or
depressed in the absence
of any mechanism for sustained growth. The net result
therefore is a pronounced
tendency towards over-production crises. The capitalist
state that could have
provided an antidote to this tendency towards
over-production by stepping up
its expenditure, and thereby absorbing a larger share of
surplus value and
helping its realisation, cannot do so because of the
opposition of finance
capital to larger state expenditure. It
follows therefore that
the incapacitation of the capitalist state as
a provider of demand at will, not
only leaves world capitalism without the requisite
exogenous stimulus for the
maintenance of sustained growth, but also pushes it
further into stagnation for
an additional reason, namely the tendency for the share
of surplus value to
rise in world output. World capitalism is thus caught in
a deep structural
crisis from which there are no obvious escape routes.
This is not to say that
capitalism will collapse, for that never happens. But,
as in the 30s, a new
conjuncture is emerging that is pregnant with historic
possibilities for the
transcendence of the system.