People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXV
No. 47 November 20, 2011 |
What Is
The European Economic Crisis About?
Prabhat
Patnaik
THE standard view of
the European economic
crisis is that it consists in the loss of confidence of the
“market” in the
creditworthiness of several European governments which have
piled up massive
debts because of their past profligacy; the solution to the
crisis
correspondingly lies in their cutting back on their
expenditures, and adopting
austerity measures, so that apparently unexceptionable precepts
like “one must
live within one’s means”, and “one must cut one’s coat according
to one’s
cloth”, which are valued by the “market”, are not henceforth
violated.
This standard view is
an instance of the
reification that characterises bourgeois theory in general. The
“market”, which
is an institution created by human beings, is seen not only as
an entity
independent of human beings, but even as having a wisdom and
sagacity of its
own that rectifies human follies and is therefore deserving of
respect and
obedience. Indeed when Mr Papandreou, the former prime minister
of Greece,
wanted to submit the austerity package, worked out by the
European Union to
restore the confidence of the “market” in the Greek government
(so that it
could roll over its public debt), for a popular referendum, on
the grounds that
it would have enormous adverse effects on the people and
therefore had to have
their sanction, there was a massive uproar from bourgeois
circles everywhere.
Even newspapers in our own country editorialised on the subject
against Mr
Papandreou’s decision. They were all aghast at this display of
quixotic
stupidity: surely the dictates of the “market” which were free
of the follies
of human beings, and of governments that tended “spinelessly” to
defer to such
follies, had to be obeyed, come what may, to avoid disaster. Mr
Papandreou,
needless to say, dropped his plan for a referendum.
In fact however the
debt accumulation of the
vulnerable European governments had little to do with any
willful profligacy on
their part. They were a product largely of two factors: the
bail-outs of
private financial institutions, effected from budgetary
resources, in the wake
of the collapse of the American housing bubble; and the fact
that governments
tended not to cut back on expenditures when their revenues fell
as a consequence
of the recession, as an act of restraining the recession itself,
ie the fact
that government policy tended to be “anti-cyclical” rather than
“pro-cyclical”.
These two factors did not of course operate with the same
intensity across all
the vulnerable countries (eg, the bail-out factor was less
important in
The “market’s”
insistence upon “austerity” and
“fiscal responsibility” therefore is a mere euphemism for the
fact that
financial interests want the governments to desist from
continuing with their
old ways of spending, including spending on what remains of the
old “Welfare
State”. There is no demand from financial circles that
governments should cut
back on their bail-out packages! The only “austerity” they
insist on is with
regard to expenditure that is targeted towards the working
people. Finance
capital wants these governments not to pursue anti-cyclical
policies, but
rather to pursue pro-cyclical policies, and to do so at the
expense of the
working people, by winding up whatever remains of the once-famed
European
Welfare State.
FINAL
ASSAULT
Put differently, what
is called the European
economic crisis is finance capital’s coup
against European social democracy, and the Welfare State it
had put in
place in the post-war period. Those measures characterised a
State, that,
despite being a bourgeois State, stood apparently above classes,
was not tied
exclusively to the interests of the capitalist class or of the
corporate-financial elements, and was responsive to an extent
towards the needs
of working people as well. The assault on that State arising
from the
ascendancy of finance, especially from the fact of globalisation of finance in a world of
nation-States, has been
going on for some time. What we are witnessing now is the final
assault, the
last push that will bring the entire edifice down. It is a final
assault to
substitute the old bourgeois State with its social democratic
stamp, apparently
standing above classes and solicitous to an extent even towards
the working
people, by a State that represents the virtual dictatorship of
finance capital.
To say this is not to
suggest a conspiracy.
Financial magnates do not sit around a table to plot political
strategies, let
alone plot “coup d’ etats” of the sort just
suggested, though they do
have remarkable co-ordination among them on several issues, and
are united to
an amazing extent by a commonness of
ideology. But an extrinsic reading of the European
economic crisis, what
it means and what it foreshadows, suggests the following: the
origin of the
debt crisis that is afflicting one European government after
another lies in the
global recession itself which
has brought down government revenues more sharply than
government expenditures,
making the old bourgeois States vulnerable, far more than ever
before, to the
caprices of global finance capital; and global finance capital
is utilising
this opportunity to enforce changes in the nature of the State
that are
extremely far-reaching, and amount in effect to a significant
attenuation of
democracy that would necessarily accompany the “austerity”
measures.
The rolling back of the
legacy of European
Social Democracy in other words would necessarily mean also a
rolling back of
democracy itself in
The very definition of
the term “crisis” used in
this context is instructive. The term “crisis” is used to refer
exclusively to
the inability of the governments to pay back or roll over their
loans, an
inability that arises from the unwillingness of finance to
entertain their
request for further credit; austerity
therefore is seen
as the resolution of
crisis. From the point of view of the working people
however austerity marks a
deepening of crisis.
The EU plan for Greece that is supposed to “resolve” the Greek
crisis does not
say a word about how long the Greek people are to endure
“austerity”, how, if
at all, they are ever going to come out of the shackles of
“austerity”, and how
they are expected to cope with the impact of “austerity” during
the period it
lasts. In short, providing finance capital cover for the loans
it has made to
the Greek government, ensuring that it does not suffer through
debt default is
all that a “resolution of the crisis” is supposed to entail, but
not any
improvement in the conditions of the people, not a turnaround in
their
fortunes. Our vocabulary itself in short undergoes a
transformation in the era
of globalised finance, when the interests of society are made
synonymous with
those of finance, but not with those of the people who
constitute it.
Many, including
economist Paul Krugman, have
been arguing that the problem of European government debt arises
only in those
countries where governments are forced to borrow from abroad,
where they have
lost the ability to borrow from within the economy, including in
particular
from their own central banks. There can of course be no two
opinions about the
fact that if a government can borrow from its central bank, ie,
through
printing money, then it will never get into a debt trap; but the
problem with
this argument lies in its implicit suggestion that it is
possible for an economy
to be thrown open to the movements of globalised finance, and
yet to remain
free of the vice-like creditor-grip of globalised finance.
In a very obvious
sense, if the government
borrows beyond what finance capital considers “safe” from its
own central bank,
then “confidence” of finance in that economy will go down,
leading to financial
outflows, including by its “own” residents, which would
necessitate the
country’s borrowing from abroad (to finance such outflows), and
hence bring in
its train similar austerity measures. But there is more to it
than that.
IILUSORY
BELIEF
The Krugman argument
detaches the question of
government debt in these vulnerable European economies from the
context of the
world recession. It is not a matter of whether a country’s
government is free
to borrow from its central bank; it is a matter of what a
country’s government
does in the context of the global recession. When there is a
sharp fall in
world aggregate demand, it has a greater or lesser recessionary
impact on all
economies of the world, greater in the case of those countries
where the dollar
wage rate (at the going exchange rate) is high relative to
labour productivity
(eg the US, or several southern European countries), and lesser
(or even a
negligible impact) where the dollar wage rate is low relative to
labour
productivity (eg China). The harder-hit countries can protect
themselves from
the impact of such recession in three possible ways.
One is through a
depreciation of the currency,
which, if their money wages do not rise (ie, their workers take
a cut in their
real wages), will improve their competitiveness (if other
countries do not
retaliate through their own depreciations) and boost their net
exports, and
hence output and employment. This is what is called a
“beggar-my-neighbour”
policy, ie, benefitting at the expense of some other country
(through larger
net exports). This however is not a very feasible option. Even
when, unlike the
Eurozone countries, a country is not on a fixed exchange rate,
there is the
possibility of retaliation from other countries (except for very
small
economies whose benefitting at the expense of others is too
negligible to
matter).
The second way, which
is what several European
economies actually tried to do, is by keeping up government
expenditure even
when government revenue goes down, ie, by enlarging their fiscal
deficits. In such a case
however even if the
government does not borrow from abroad to meet its fiscal
deficit, the country
nonetheless will have to borrow from abroad. The very fact
of protecting
the economy from recession through a larger fiscal deficit would
mean that the
country’s imports will be kept up, even as its exports suffer
because of the
recession in the global economy. Hence the country will have to
borrow from abroad
even if its government does not; and this would bring the same
set of problems
that
The third way is for
the government to boost
domestic demand (through a larger fiscal deficit if necessary,
as in the second
case), but to impose
simultaneously
controls over capital and trade flows, ie,
to effect a process of
delinking, not only from “globalisation”, but even from
groupings like the
European Union (unless such Unions themselves protect their
constituent
economies from the global recession through a policy of internal expansion, combined with “de-linking”
from
“globalisation”).
Of course, if there is
a concerted global action
for increasing world aggregate demand, then that is a separate
matter. But such
action is not on the agenda. In its absence, the belief that an
economy can be
protected from the crisis even if it remains exposed to global
financial and
trade flows, ie, within a neo-liberal regime committed to
“globalisation”, is
mere illusion.