People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXV
No. 46 November 13, 2011 |
No Evidence of Learning
C P Chandrasekhar
THE
government and
In
a surprise move the Reserve Bank of
There
is reason to believe that it is the second of these arguments
that has
influenced the RBI to resort to this move. Unwilling (and also
unable) to
restrict credit flow because of the fear that it will affect
growth too
adversely, the central bank has decided to maximise the impact
on demand of the
thirteen interest rate hikes it has announced in recent
months. The RBI holds
that the policy has been on the anvil and had been seriously
considered a
couple of times in the recent past. It had also issued,
earlier this year, a discussion
paper on “Deregulation of Savings Bank Deposit Interest
Rates”, which though
presenting the “pros and cons” involved, was all too clearly
inclined towards
the pros. Despite these early signals, the timing of the final
decision was a
surprise.
Savings
bank deposits fall in between current account deposits that
pay no interest
since they are maintained largely for transactions purposes,
and term deposits
or fixed deposits that are seen as pure savings products
likely to be held till
they mature, and are paid interest at rates depending on their
term. Broadly
speaking, the longer the period for which the bank has a
guarantee that it has
access to the money deposited, the higher would be the
interest rate paid to
the depositor. For some time now, banks have had the freedom
to set the
interest rates they offer depositors on term deposits.
Savings
bank deposits, from which depositors are substantially free to
withdraw their
money, are seen as being partly held for transaction purposes
and partly for
saving purposes. This makes them eligible for an interest rate
that is lower
than that offered on term deposits. In
LIBERALISATION OF
BANKING POLICY
Regulation
of deposit interest rates is by no means specific to
If
competition between banks to attract deposits raises the cost
of funds, while banks
are locked into loans charging interest rates that are not
changeable till
maturity, the interest rate spread gets squeezed leading to
lower profits or
losses. Since savings deposits are seen as partly savings
products and not just
maintained for transaction purposes, banks tend to treat these
as part of their
core deposits, which determines how much they lend. Based on
the average
monthly minimum balance maintained on savings deposits, the
RBI too identifies
90 per cent of savings bank deposits as “core” deposits. This
implies the banks
can lend relatively long against such deposits, increasing the
probability of
an interest-rate mismatch if deposit rates rise sharply due to
competition. This
would result in a situation where banks suffer losses, turn
fragile and face
closure. This is in part what happened to the thrift
institutions that went
bankrupt during the Savings and Loan Crisis of the 1980s in
the
But
this was not the only danger. Even if banks don’t face a
profit squeeze, the
rising cost of capital as a result of competition between
banks to attract
deposits, would force banks to find investment and lending
avenues that offer
higher rates of return. Higher returns are inevitably
associated with higher
risks. If banks are not allowed to diversify into these areas,
the demand to
remove such barriers is bound to increase, forcing a
liberalisation of banking
policy. In that event, a consequence of the deregulation of
interest rates
could be an increase in the exposure of banks to “sensitive”
sectors like real
estate and the stock market. This could in turn lead to a
speculative spiral,
as was experienced in many countries including
Finally,
as the
BREACHING THE
LAST DYKE
It
could be argued that these issues are not of much relevance
since savings
deposits are only one form (and not the dominant form) in
which households
invest their savings. Since interest rates on term deposits
are already free,
the effect of liberalisation of rates on savings deposits are
expected to be
marginal and manageable. This, however, is not all true. The
access to cash or
liquidity that savings deposits offer to depositors, have made
them an
important means of holding savings for households. The
household sector
accounts for close to 85 per cent of all savings deposits in
As
noted earlier, banks treat a substantial proportion of these
deposits as “core”
deposits, lending relatively long based on them. In 2009, 57
per cent of the
advances of scheduled commercial banks as a group were in the
form of term
loans. The figure in the case of domestic private sector banks
went up to as
much as 69 per cent. If the average cost of funds available to
these banks rises,
their profits could take a hit since they are substantially
tied into long term
lending contracts, As a corollary, over time, as banks adjust
their portfolios,
they would be unwilling to lend long, affecting one source of
longer term
finance. Their search for better returns would also increase
the pressure to
avoid lending to sections that must be reached as part of
financial inclusion
and to the priority sectors of the economy.
These
consequences can be more intense in
A
likely outcome of interest rate liberalisation would be a
decline of the share
of public banks in savings deposits. In order to wean
depositors away from
public banks, in the aftermath of interest rate
liberalisation, private banks
may hike interest rates on savings deposits, so as to increase
their presence
in the domestic market. Public sector banks would be forced to
follow or lose a
part of their business or both. This could damage the
profitability of the
public banks, which even now bear a disproportionate share of
the social
obligations imposed on the banking system. Further, they would
be forced into
finding ways of reducing their commitment to financial
inclusion. In sum, the
likelihood is that the liberalisation of savings deposit rates
would weaken the
public banking system and be adverse from the points of view
of growth, of
financial inclusion and of stability.
Judged
by timing,