People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXV
No.
38 September 18, 2011 |
Austerity
Versus Stimulus
Prabhat
Patnaik
IT
is obviously silly to push for austerity in
the midst of a recession, not just silly but cruel, since it prolongs
the pain
of unemployment. The recession is caused by a deficiency of aggregate
demand.
To overcome it what is necessary is an increase in demand which
requires larger
expenditure. Since private expenditure on consumption is restrained in
a
recession by the fact of unemployment and low income, since private
expenditure
on investment is restrained by the fact that when markets are not
expanding
capitalists have little desire to increase their productive capacity,
and since
the rest of the world’s net expenditure on the country’s goods can
increase
only through a shift of its demand from elsewhere, ie, by a
“beggar-my-neighbour” policy, which is no solution to the overall
problem and will
invite retaliation from others, the sole plausible way that the
recession can
be overcome is through an increase in government expenditure, ie
through a
fiscal stimulus. Austerity being the very opposite of this will clearly
worsen
rather than improve things.
But
then why is there a push for austerity even
in the midst of a recession? The obvious answer is that finance capital
does
not want a proactive State engaged in demand management. If the State
intervenes to fix the level of activity in a capitalist economy, then
the
“state of confidence” of the capitalists which determines it otherwise,
ie, in
the absence of such State intervention, ceases to matter. This removes
any need
to appease capitalists, to bolster their “state of confidence” through
all
kinds of inducements, in the “interests of society”, ie, for the
amelioration
of socially pressing problems like unemployment. Since a prominent
measure of appeasement
of the capitalists is to bolster the stock market, ie, to act in
conformity
with the caprices of finance capital, State intervention in demand
management
through fiscal means is anathema for finance capital, which therefore
uses all
the resources at its command for preaching the virtues of “sound
finance” (ie, of
balancing budgets). The demand for austerity in the midst of a
recession, ie,
for cutting down government expenditure in tandem with the reduction in
tax
revenue that occurs in such a period, is thus in keeping with the
predilections
of finance capital. To effect this self-serving policy, finance capital
and its
spokesmen advance the argument that such austerity will actually
overcome the
recession, which, as already mentioned, is a silly argument.
SILLY
ARGUMENT
But
just as “false consciousness” also has an
element of “truth”, this patently silly argument for austerity is not
without a
rationale within its own context. And that context is the
following.
Since finance capital believes, even if completely wrongly, that
a
fiscal stimulus, in the form of a larger fiscal deficit, is harmful for
the
economy, such a deficit may well undermine the “state of confidence” of
the
financiers, and hence, via its impact on the stock market and other
financial
markets, of the capitalists as a whole. Now, those who advocate a
fiscal
stimulus typically have in mind a scenario where the revival of
activity
following such a stimulus, brings about, in turn, larger private
investment and
consumption expenditure, such that the need for such a stimulus
disappears
after a while; in other words they
visualise the stimulus necessarily as a temporary phenomenon, simply to
get the
economy “out of the woods”, after which “business as usual” can take
over.
This, to repeat, is based on the understanding that private investment
picks up
once the level of activity picks up, that it simply follows changes in
the
level of activity. But if the act of stimulating the economy by the
State also
has the effect of undermining the state of confidence of the
capitalists,
then the revival of activity may not be
followed by the hoped-for revival of private investment
expenditure, or may
at best be followed by an anemic revival of such expenditure, in which
case the
sustenance of the revival would require the persistence of the fiscal
stimulus.
The fiscal stimulus in short may not be the temporary phenomenon it is
supposed
to be but may well turn out to be a more durable affair.
This,
of course, should not matter in itself. A
fiscal deficit which increases government borrowing, actually puts
the extra
savings in the hands of the capitalists that finance such borrowing.
The
extra government borrowing in other words does not come out of any
pre-existing
pool of private savings, ie, it does not cause any diversion of a
pre-existing
pool from other uses to lending to the government.
This
is a point so little understood, even by
well-known professional economists, that a word on it may be in order.
If the
government decides to increase its spending by 100 which it borrows,
then
demand increases for domestic and foreign goods by that amount. This
raises
domestic and foreign output, which increases employment, and hence
further
increases demand and output. This process goes on until an amount of
additional
savings to the tune of 100 has been generated out of this additional
output in
the hands of the domestic private sector and of the rest of the world.
In other
words, whatever the government borrows, generates an equal amount of
loanable
resources in the hands of the private sector and the rest of the world.
There
should in principle therefore be no limits
to government borrowing. Besides, the government differs from any
private
individual in the obvious sense that it has the power to tax, so that
the
problem of repayment of debt is also not a matter of concern. True, if
the
tax-GDP ratio has to rise continuously to service government debt, then
beyond
a point this debt may become unsustainable (unless the government
decides to
repudiate it); but even this problem is not of any concern as long as
the
average interest rate on government debt is less than the rate of
growth of the
economy, which is not a particularly stringent requirement. It follows
then
that even if the fiscal stimulus becomes a durable affair, this in
itself
should not be a matter of much concern.
MARRED
BY
CONTRADICTION
But
the real hurdle to the persistence of a
fiscal deficit is the loss of “confidence” of the financiers
in the government. This may sound
ironical, and indeed is, but no less real for that. The loanable
resources that
any government fiscal deficit generates are borrowed by the government
through
the intermediation of the financiers. In other words, the loanable
resources
generated in the hands of the domestic private sector or of the rest of
the
world are held as deposits of (or loans to) financial intermediaries
like banks
which in turn buy government securities with them. Even when the
domestic
private sector or the rest of the world directly buy government
securities (as
the Chinese are doing in the
It
follows that State intervention through a
fiscal stimulus to overcome the recession must reckon with the need to
confront
finance capital: the State must be willing to run fiscal deficits not
just as a
temporary phenomenon but even persistently, (since the “state of
confidence” of
the capitalists may get undermined by the very fact of fiscal deficits
to a
point where private investment does not easily revive); and it must
also be
willing to exert adequate control over the financial system to ensure
that
public borrowing is always financed, so that the State does not become
a
prisoner to the caprices of financiers. The problem with the economists
in the
To
say, as many “progressive” American
economists do, that the only impediment to a fiscal stimulus, which,
let us
agree, can alleviate the problem of the recession, is the
intellectual failure of its opponents who are stuck with a
wrong theory, is to underestimate the systemic
opposition to it; it is to see the crisis as a mere policy failure,
and not
as being embedded in the system itself. The opponents of a fiscal
stimulus no
doubt have an intellectual position that is shallow; but that position
is the
outcome of a systemic reality that is deep. If the crisis is embedded
in the
system itself then overcoming it must entail some systemic change, in
the
absence of which it would persist. The debate in
Of
course, it may be argued that for
“progressive economists” in the