People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXV
No.
23 June 05, 2011 |
LAND
ACQUISITION DEBATE
Some
Issues for Reflection
Archana
Prasad
IN its meeting of May 25,
2011, the National Advisory Council (NAC) led by Mrs Sonia Gandhi made
some
suggestions to re-look and revise the Land Acquisition and the
Resettlement and
Rehabilitation Bills. It floated a discussion paper and suggested that
both
these bills should be combined into a single bill entitled the National
Development, Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and Resettlement Act. The
discussion paper is a great advancement over the Land Acquisition
Amendment Act
2007, but leaves many questions unanswered without whose resolution
there can
be little effective control on corporate penetration in resource rich
areas. At
the heart of the debate are also the recent policies of the
introduction of
private capital in resource based industries like mining. It is
therefore not
surprising that most of the social unrest has been resulting from
displacement
and dispossession of land in resource rich tribal areas. Outside these
areas,
several farmers and fisherfolk have protested against land acquisition
and
special economic zones like the recent protests in Uttar Pradesh and
many small
local mobilisations in coastal areas of
In this context there is
a widespread desire by democratic and grassroots movements to turn the
Land
Acquisition Act into an instrument of control over private land
grabbing. If
the NAC discussion paper is analysed, we may find that there is some
headway in
this direction, so far as building a political consciousness is
concerned. But
it is clear that the struggle to achieve this goal will be a hard and
arduous
one. This is reflected by the way state governments here have reached a
near
unanimity in all perspectives on land acquisition that the Act of 1894
needs to
be amended. But the direction of the amendment is under debate, and the
key
questions that have emerged are: Who should acquire the land? What
purpose
should constitute public purpose? What type of compensation should be
paid for
the land?
WHO SHOULD
ACQUIRE LAND
The amendment bill introduced
in 2007 made certain fundamental changes in the original colonial law.
However,
many of these changes were not geared towards meeting the needs of the
most
vulnerable people. One of its major flaws was that the acquisition of
land by
private companies was largely left out of the scope of the bill. The
bill held
that if a private party acquired 70 per cent of the land at market
prices, then
the state could acquire the remaining 30 per cent of it under the
“public
purpose” provision. The amendment raised the key issue about how
acquisition of
land for private purposes was to be handled.
In one of the perspectives,
it is being argued that state should acquire land for “public purposes”
which
comprises only developmental and infrastructural work to be done by the
government. In this case, corporate buyers should buy land directly
from the
farmers without any state intervention. The Trinamul Congress is one of
the
biggest votaries of this view, which will put the farmers at the mercy
of the
industrialists. This view largely represents those who think that the
farmers
will get the best price for land through the market. It further
attempts to
absolve the state of any responsibility towards those impacted by the
project.
This is a politically
convenient stand to take as it ensures that any opposition to land
acquisition
is to be dealt with by the corporates themselves, and that any
resistance is
dealt with as a law and order problem only. The instances of state
repression
in favour of the corporate landholders in resource rich areas have
increased in
the recent times, and many ongoing conflicts are being subjected to
police
repression rather than being resolved by negotiation. In a variant of
this view,
the discussion paper prepared by the NAC has had some members
advocating that a
separate regulatory mechanism should be worked out to regulate the land
markets
through the declaration of a minimum land price. Whether this is in
itself
sufficient to control and regulate the malpractices of the private
sector is open
to doubt.
Another argument being
put forward is that the state must be an active participant in the
process of
acquisition. It is argued that all land acquisition should take place
through
the state even if it is for private players. The NAC discussion paper
goes into
this issue in some length and elaborates it as the view articulated by
one of
its members. The argument made is that the state can acquire land for
both
public and industrial purposes. In its own press release, the NAC
stated that
state should acquire land “for any other purpose useful to the general
public
including companies if 70 per cent of the project affected people give
their
written consent.” Proponents of this argument contend that any direct
acquisition
by private parties will only lead to greater intrusion by land mafias
in
resource rich areas. Here the classification of “public purpose” is not
done on
the basis of the intent of the land use, but on the principle that two
thirds
of the project affected people should agree to the land acquisition
process. If
this is the case, it needs to be clarified that the written consent
needed for
acquisition should not be only of the landholders. It should also be of
the
people who depend on the land in terms of seasonal and non-farm
occupation
since the definition of project affected people also includes these
people.
Though the NAC paper states this difference of opinion, it does not
take any
position as to which one of the systems is better, and thus it reflects
the
dilemma of the current public debate.
SEPARATING PUBLIC &
COMMERCIAL PURPOSES
It is clear that if
greater social control is to be maintained over all the land
acquisition
processes, then the state has to play a central role in the
acquisition,
rehabilitation and resettlement process. Further, the intended uses of
the
acquired land must follow a land use plan that has been approved by the
concerned
state’s legislative assembly. As stated by the NAC, and demanded by
democratic
forces, projects requiring acquisition of land must prove that less
displacing
technological and land use options are not available to them. In
addition, both
the project as well as the acquisition of land must have prior informed
consent
of the project affected people. In all cases, provisions must be made
to ensure
that the land is used only for the project for which it has been
acquired and
is not resold or transferred for profit making purposes. Any new land
use
should also require the assent of the Gram
Sabha or any other local self-government. But even here, the
definition of “public
purpose” should not include activities that can yield commercial
profits for
the state as well as the private sector. In both cases the conditions
specified
for acquisition and determination of compensation should be different.
Both ownership and
intent are important in the definition of “public purpose.” Public
purpose can
itself be classified into two broad categories. First are the state’s
developmental projects of importance to the local area development,
which would
be bringing direct socio-economic benefits to the local residents. Here
the
local self-governments should be involved in the screening of the
projects, and
the latter’s impact on the local societies should be part of the social
impact
assessment. Second, in case of larger strategic and infrastructural
public
projects for non-local benefits, the state and local self-governments
should
arrive at some agreement where a percentage of the non-monetary
benefits and
proceeds should be invested back into the local area. This may also
mean
altering the design of the project. Hence the compensation from these
projects
should include a plan for development of the local area, apart from
rehabilitation and resettlement. In both these cases, the projects
should be
largely state owned and the land should be acquired at the base market
price
determined and declared at the time of acquisition. This should be in
addition
to the other comprehensive measures (solatium,
meeting of basic needs, employment etc) that have been suggested by
movements
from time to time and also discussed in the NAC paper.
If the project is
commercial in nature and the acquisition is being done by the state for
private
industry, then the conditions of purchase should be different. The
project
should be screened, prior informed consent for the project must be
obtained
from the project affected people, and the social impact assessment
should
ensure that there is no adverse impact on the economy of the region.
The
compensation and price of purchase should be higher than the base
market price
(on which the land is acquired for public purposes) and should include
the opportunity
costs and the net present value of resources (especially in case of
extractive
industries), among other things. Annuities should be paid in terms of
the share
of the profits, in addition to the requirements of the rehabilitation
plans.
Further, a fund should be created to which the private sector should
contribute
monetarily, and which should be included in the cost of the project.
The cost
of any ecological and social damage to the area in which the project is
located,
must also be estimated and included in the project cost.
Above all, adequate
rehabilitation and resettlement options, discussed at some length by
the NAC
paper, should be available to all the project affected people. An
integrated
land use plan, which is made in a participatory manner and approved by
democratically elected institutions, should form the bedrock of all
acquisition
processes. This will ensure a pathway for a more balanced and just
developmental process that does not compromise on food, livelihood and
social
security for the most vulnerable sections of the nation.