People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
52 December 26, 2010 |
Growth and
Impoverishment
Prabhat
Patnaik
NOT a day
passes without some
official spokesman or the other recounting
WRONG
PERCEPTION
This
perception which has
many adherents is plain wrong. There can be alternative ways of
achieving
economic growth, and the social impact of growth depends upon how it is achieved. The growth process
currently underway in the Indian economy, which is rooted in
I am not
resorting to
hyperbole. The empirical evidence for absolute impoverishment in the
recent
period of high growth is overwhelming; and the reason for it is also
fairly
straightforward. Let us look at the evidence first. The official
criterion for
the identification of poverty (until it was changed recently after the
Tendulkar Committee report) has been the intake of 2400 calories or
less per
person per day in rural India and 2100 calories or less in urban India.
By this
criterion, poverty has certainly increased: direct measurement of
calorie
intake suggests that 74.5 per cent of the rural population was “poor”
in 1993-4,
and 87 per cent in 2004-5; the corresponding figures were 56 per cent
and 63
per cent respectively for the urban population. (These figures, based
on NSS
data, are from Utsa Patnaik, Economic and
Political Weekly, Jan 28-Feb 4, 2010, and their veracity cannot be
questioned).
Foodgrain
absorption
figures confirm this conclusion. Per capita foodgrain absorption
(defined as
net output minus net exports minus net increase in stocks) which, in
round
figures, was 200 kilograms per annum in
“British India” at the beginning of the twentieth century declined
drastically
to less than 150 kilograms by the time of independence. Strenuous
efforts by
successive governments in independent
Two arguments
are
typically advanced against the identification of reduced foodgrain
intake with
increased poverty. The first states that there tends to be a
diversification of
consumption away from foodgrains as incomes increase, so that reduced
foodgrain
intake signifies, contrary to my claim, a qualitative improvement in
the
consumption basket, and hence in living standards.
This argument
however is
wrong. With increased incomes, the direct
consumption of foodgrains may go down, but the indirect
consumption of foodgrains, as processed food (such as
cornflakes) or as feedgrains for animal products (such as mutton, pork,
chicken
etc) goes up; as a result the total
absorption of foodgrain per capita, direct and indirect taken
together,
increases. In the
The second
argument states
that the reason for reduced foodgrain intake even among lower income
groups is
larger expenditure on other things, in particular healthcare; and this
is indicative
of changing “tastes”, associated with an improved quality of life, and
hence
economic betterment.
The fallacy
of this
argument lies in its underlying assumption that anyone, even a poor
man,
compares at the margin the satisfaction to be derived from consuming
more food
with that from taking his child to the hospital when the child is ill.
This
assumption is wrong. In most people’s perception the latter has
absolute
priority. Since this perception could not have emerged suddenly over
the last
decade, when per capita foodgrain absorption declined precipitously,
the cause
for this decline is likely to be a rise in healthcare costs
over this period.
Such a rise
has certainly
been a feature of the neo-liberal era, owing to increasing drug prices
and
privatisation of healthcare. Hence, the fact that expenditure on
healthcare has
gone up even at the expense of food
intake in the last decade, can only be indicative of
impoverishment, rather
than of an improved quality of life.
DECLINING
PURCHASING
POWER
The basic
reason for this
impoverishment is reduced purchasing power in real terms in the hands
of the
bulk of the working population, which in turn is due to two phenomena.
First,
the growth process has been accompanied by what Marx had called a
process of “primitive
accumulation of capital”, whereby vast numbers of peasants, petty
producers
like fishermen and craftsmen, marginal groups like the tribal
population,
suffer either outright dispossession or a squeeze on their real
incomes, for
the benefit of large capitalists, speculators and the financial
interests.
Big retail
chains come up
to displace petty traders; agribusiness comes in to squeeze the
peasantry; land
grabbing financiers come in to displace peasants from their land for
real
estate and spurious infrastructure projects; tribal people are evicted
to make
room for mining projects; and petty producers of all descriptions
everywhere
get trapped between rising input prices caused by the withdrawal of
State
subsidies and declining output prices caused by the withdrawal of State
protection from world commodity price trends. When we add to all this
the rise
in the cost of living, because of the privatisation of education,
health and
several essential services, which affects the entire working
population, we can
gauge the virulence of the primitive
accumation that is unleashed.
This process
of primitive
accumulation is at the same time unaccompanied by any significant
increase in the
employment of wage workers (as distinct from white collar
professionals) in the
capitalist sector. This is because of the rapid rate of technological
and
structural change that a changing demand pattern, owing to rising
income
disparities, generates in a “liberalised” economy. Hence the victims of
primitive accumulation cannot get absorbed as wage-workers under
capitalism.
They either join the reserve army of labour, or linger on in their old
occupations, taking a cut in their real incomes in both cases. Besides,
this
very fact of a swelling labour reserve also keeps the wages of employed
workers
low, even as labour productivity rises, contributing further to the
growing
income disparities.
Any
acceleration of growth
simply reproduces the problem on an even larger scale. The displacement
of
tribals and peasants occurs on an even larger scale, the expropriation
of petty
producers occurs to an even greater extent, while the rate of growth of
labour
productivity in the organised capitalist sector increases with
increased growth
rate, keeping labour absorption into this sector as constricted as
ever. The
view that with a higher growth rate poverty will be eradicated remains
a
chimera; poverty on the contrary only increases with the growth rate.
And the
constraint on public
expenditure, typical of neo-liberal economies, where tax concessions
reduce
revenue and “fiscal responsibility” legislation curbs government
borrowing,
ensures that “social protection” measures remain both anaemic and
amenable to
sudden, arbitrary and sporadic cuts. Growth under the neo-liberal
dispensation
therefore, far from being a condition for the amelioration of poverty,
becomes
an instrument for the impoverishment of large segments of the working
population.