People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
45 November 07, 2010 |
The
Dilemma of the European Left
Prabhat
Patnaik
THE
recent developments
in
The
workers today not
only do not have any political demands,
which shows how far political transformation has receded from the
agenda of
even the most militant of present-day workers’ struggles; they do not
even have
any alternative vision of an economic arrangement
different from the present one, which could act as a transitional
demand
leading to a politicisation of the current struggle over a period of
time. In
other words the present struggle, remarkably militant though it is, is
not only
not informed by any alternative vision, of an arrangement different
from
capitalism; it is not even informed by any alternative vision different from European capitalism in its
present form. It is an uncompromising struggle to defend the gains
of the
Welfare State, but within capitalism as
it exists today. The uncompromising nature of the struggle is
admirable;
but the absence of any perspective on how to resolve the contradiction
between
the Welfare State and the demands of contemporary capitalism is a
serious flaw.
This absence in turn is traceable to a fundamental problem faced by the
European Left.
INDUBITABLE
FACTS
The
fact that wage cuts,
if resorted to by each country to overcome its crisis, aggravate the
crisis for
all; the fact that exchange rate depreciations, if undertaken by each
country
as a means of resolving its crisis, aggravate the crisis for all, are
indubitable. These measures could work in the case of one single
country in
raising its aggregate demand through an increase in its net exports,
provided
it was alone in following them and no other country adopted similar
measures.
But when all follow such measures they collectively ensure a worsening
of the
crisis for each one of them. What appears to each individual country as
rational, is in the aggregate irrational.
The
opposite is also true.
What is collectively rational, may be individually irrational, in the
sense
that if all countries followed similar measures then all would be
better off,
but if a single country followed this measure while others did not then
it would
come to grief. A rise in wages everywhere for instance in the midst of
a
crisis, or a synchronous increase in the fiscal deficits in all
countries, will
improve the situation for all. But if only one country increased its
wages
while others did not, then in a universe of liberalised trade its
aggregate
demand is likely to decrease through a reduction in its net exports;
likewise
if one country increased its fiscal deficit while others did not, then
in a
universe of financial fluidity it runs the risk of financial outflows
and hence
insolvency.
It
follows that if
Welfare State measures have to be strengthened as a means of overcoming
crisis,
then quite apart from the political objections
to any such move from capitalists, and in particular from financial
quarters
(who dislike all forms of State activism except those that directly
serve their
own interests), there is another fundamental hurdle. And this consists
in the
fact that such measures should either be adopted collectively
by all, or by an individual country provided it de-links
itself from the
universe of liberalised trade and financial flows. And exactly the
same
holds for the defence of Welfare state measures.
Now,
co-ordinated action
involving all major actors in the global economy, does not appear
feasible at
present. On the other hand, the Left in no country in
Of
course, feasible or
not, the fact that the European Left has not raised the demand for
globally
co-ordinated fiscal action is somewhat surprising. During the Great
Depression
of the 1930s, several authors, including some German trade unionists
and also John
Maynard Keynes, had asked for a co-ordinated fiscal stimulus among
major capitalist
economies as a means of overcoming the crisis. Something of that sort
was
talked about at the beginning of the current crisis too, and several
countries
did in fact undertake fiscal stimuli. But the stimuli were weak, and a
clamour
for rolling them back began soon, because of which there is now an
actual
roll-back in some countries, like Britain, and an attempt at a roll
back in others
like France which is being resisted.
On
a superficial glance
it may appear as if the fiscal stimuli that were provided in the wake
of the
crisis were quite strong, since the fiscal deficit as a percentage of
GDP rose
dramatically in major capitalist economies. But much of the increased
fiscal
deficit was for shoring up the financial system and had little effect
on stimulating
aggregate demand. So, while the so-called stimulus was not much of a
stimulus to
aggregate demand, though the increased fiscal deficit deceived people
into
believing otherwise, what is now being attempted for pruning this
deficit will
certainly impinge adversely on aggregate demand.
STAGGERING
IMPLICATIONS
Besides,
the class
implications of the post-crisis fiscal policies in the capitalist world
are
quite staggering. The enhanced fiscal deficit was meant to aid finance
capital;
but its curtailment comes at the cost of the Welfare State. In other
words, the
Welfare State is being sacrificed, workers’ living standards are being
rolled
back, as a post-facto price for buttressing the position of finance
capital. A
more brazen example of class-aggrandizement masquerading as respectable
economic theory cannot be imagined. But
the European working classes’ fight against this aggrandizement takes
the form not
of attacking the totality of the underlying arrangement, or suggesting
an
alternative totality, but of merely resisting the attack on the Welfare
State
within this very totality.
Apart
from the two
alternatives for defending and strengthening the Welfare State
mentioned above,
viz. national-level delinking from globalisation, and global fiscal
co-ordination,
there is a third possible way open to Europe, and that is a unilateral
fiscal stimulus by Euro-zone
countries alone. Even without waiting for a co-ordinated fiscal
stimulus
involving all major countries, and I
mean a genuine stimulus that increases aggregate demand, not hand-outs
to
finance, Euro-zone countries alone could simultaneously and
synchronously
expand government expenditures financed by fiscal deficits.
Some
of the increased
demand generated by such expansion will no doubt leak out to
non-European
economies. But the very fact of a co-ordinated fiscal stimulus in
The
problem with this alternative
however is that even though single-country nationalism is not viable in
Putting
it differently,
despite European integration, pan-European consciousness remains weak,
too weak
perhaps to sustain a co-ordinated fiscal stimulus across Europe for the
defence
and strengthening of the Welfare State in all member countries as a
means to
overcome the crisis. If the Union government in India announces a
North-East
package, or if it increases the fiscal deficit for undertaking larger
expenditure in some particular part of the country, then this does not
provoke
a storm of protests elsewhere. The reason, which lies juridically in
the fact
that India constitutes one single nation-State, lies effectively in the
existence of a reasonably strong pan-Indian consciousness. A
pan-European
consciousness of this kind does not exist, which forecloses for the
Left this
third option as well.
DILEMMA
OF THE
EUROPEAN
LEFT
The
dilemma of the
European Left therefore is that while it must resist the rolling back
of the
Welfare State, it cannot suggest any alternative to the existing
economic
arrangements of capitalism within which alone its resistance can be
successful,
and which can then constitute a transitional demand for a political
offensive
of the working classes. A co-ordinated global fiscal stimulus is
infeasible
(though the Left must ask for it more loudly than it does); a
national-level de-linking
from globalisation is impractical and invokes single-country
nationalisms that
the European Left opposes; and a pan-European co-ordinated fiscal
stimulus runs
the risk of stimulating reactionary single-country nationalisms that
will
strengthen the Right and fascist elements.
Nonetheless,
the
European Left must press for a co-ordinated fiscal stimulus among
Euro-zone
countries for the defence and strengthening of the Welfare State as a
means of combating
the crisis. For this however it has to overcome a certain intellectual
reservation that exists within its own ranks, which consists in a
distrust of
all “nationalism”, including even any pan-European “supra-nationalism”.
Such
a distrust of
“nationalism” which is not confined to the European Left alone but
characterises
Left thinking elsewhere too, is no doubt justified to a degree.
Nationalism,
even when it is of the inclusive anti-imperialist kind that we find in
the
third world, has the potential to become “closed” and reactionary; in
the
context of Europe where “nationalism” has been a weapon not of defence
against
imperialism and aggression but of perpetrating imperialism and
aggression, this
reactionary potential, even of a pan-European Left-led
“supra-nationalism”, is
immeasurably greater. The Left naturally shrinks from it and sections
of the Left
visualise a direct transition from the current regime of globalisation
to a
global socialist order.
But
when such a direct
transition is not possible, when globally-coordinated working class
actions are
not on the horizon, when resistance to the consequences of
neo-liberalism is
taking militant but localised forms, the Left has no alternative but to
accept
a more or less prolonged transitional phase of national or pan-national
(as in
the case of Europe) de-linking from the current global order before the
world
can witness a new form of internationalism that is driven not by
finance
capital but by socialist praxis.
True,
if this isolated
de-linking gets inordinately protracted then the distortions intrinsic
to it
may become too strong to resist. But if the unit of resistance to
neo-liberal
globalisation is large enough (like the EU as a whole), then, given the
internationalist perspective of the resistance itself, the chances of
thwarting
the reactionary potential of the “nationalism” that such resistance
unleashes
transitionally, are that much greater. At any rate, to invoke this
potential as
an argument for reconciling oneself to neo-liberal globalisation, until
the
arrival out of the blue of some “promised dawn” when the entire order
can be
changed in its totality, is unproductive.
For
us in India there is
a sense of déjà vu about this debate.
Nobody was more sensitive to the reactionary possibilities of
“nationalism”
than Rabindranath Tagore, and nobody, despite being aware of these
reactionary
possibilities, was as clear-sighted about the necessity of
“nationalism” as a weapon
of struggle against imperialism as Mahatma Gandhi. The Left, especially
the
European Left, since Europe is becoming the leading theatre of
resistance to
the depredations of neo-liberal capitalism, has to be equally
clear-sighted
today. It has to come out with alternative transitional demands that
necessarily entail a “retreat” from contemporary globalisation.
Slavoj
Zizek wants not a
withdrawal from the European project but a carrying forward of this
project to
a European working class upsurge. But the French, German and Greek
workers
cannot be expected to combine on a revolutionary project if they are
not even
united on a set of transitional trade union demands. Until this unity
comes
about, the militant resistance of the French or the Greek workers, even
though
heart-warming, will not translate itself into productive political
action.