People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
43 October 24, 2010 |
World
Economy: The Elusive Recovery
C
P Chandrasekhar
THE optimism that overcame global
governments when growth figures for the last quarter of 2009 were
released is
fast receding. Growth has slowed sharply in the subsequent two quarters
and
unemployment rates are in danger of rising further. In the
Not surprisingly, on September 9, the OECD
which had, like many other organisations, been upbeat about the
recovery of the
world economy from the Great Recession, issued an interim assessment
that
reflected a new scepticism. “The world economic recovery may be slowing
faster
than previously anticipated”, it argued, with growth in the Group of
Seven
countries in the second half of 2010 projected at around 1½ per cent on
an
annualised basis compared with its earlier estimate of around 2½ per
cent in the
Economic Outlook released in May.
This was of significance because 2009,
which was otherwise a depressing year, ended on an optimistic note.
Considering
the year as a whole, growth was negative in the leading economies and
highly so
in
However, as noted above, by the time full
year’s figures for 2009 were available there was cause for optimism.
The
quarter-on-quarter annual growth rates seemed to suggest that the
recession was
already bottoming out in the third quarter of 2009 and had touched
respectable
levels in the last quarter, especially in the
DASHED
OPTIMISM
Unfortunately, that optimism has been
dashed by performance during the next two quarters, when growth has
decelerated
quite sharply in the
It must be noted that the IMF has been more
optimistic in its World Economic Outlook
released in time for the annual meetings of the World Bank and the IMF
held in
October. It projects world output to grow at 4.8 per cent during 2010,
as
compared with a contraction of 0.6 per cent in 2009. This, of course,
is
largely because of the optimism generated by the sharp recovery in the
emerging
markets of Asia and
The recognition of these differences is
partly visible in the optimistic growth projections. The emerging and
developing economies are expected to grow by 7.1 per cent in 2010, as
compared
with 2.5 per cent in 2009. On the other hand, the advanced economies
are
expected to grow by 2.7 per cent in 2010, as opposed to the contraction
of 3.2
per cent they experienced in 2009. This modest recovery too is to an
extent due
to the significant turnaround in the newly industrialised Asian
economies
(included by the IMF among the advanced) from -0.9 per cent in 2009 to
7.8 per
cent in 2010. In sum, the core of capitalism as we know it today is
even in the
optimistic projections of the IMF expected to grow rather slowly this
year.
The fundamental problems remain the same.
Household balance sheets are under strain because of the legacy of debt
accumulated during the boom. Unemployment is curtailing current
incomes. And
credit is either unavailable to or being avoided by those who need to
expand
consumption because of a collapse of net worth. In the event, private
consumption expenditure in much of the developed world, which stagnated
in real
terms in 2008 and declined significantly in 2009, is unlikely to
recover
substantially in 2010. On the other hand, governments across the
developed
world, overcome by conservative fears of excess public debt, are
holding back
on public expenditure or resorting to severe austerity measures that
are
sparking public dissent as in parts of
In sum, the fear that an early retreat from
the stimulus would deliver a second dip is still with us, at least in
the
developed world. Even in the
WRONG
BELIEF
This would imply that a major stimulus is
in order. But when talk of the stimulus arises it takes the form only
of a
monetary stimulus or “quantitative easing”. This involves large doses
or
several billions of dollars of asset purchases by the Federal Reserve
aimed at
injecting liquidity into the economy and driving down interest rates.
The
problem with this approach is the belief that the desire or inducement
to spend
or invest exists and the problem is the lack of credit to fuel such
spending.
That is a belief that has been proved wrong many times over in recent
history.
Yet there are myriad ways in which liquidity is sought to be injected
into the
system. For example, the Treasury department has announced a
$1.5billion
programme aimed at small businesses and designed to trigger $15billion
in
additional private lending.
What the quantitative easing does is that it
lowers UN interest rates, widens the differential between interest
rates in
that country and elsewhere in the world and encourages, therefore, the
carry
trade. When additional liquidity is injected, financial investors
(rather than
industrial firms) borrow dollars at low interest rates, convert those
dollars
to currencies of countries where interest rates or financial returns
are high
or just higher and make an investment to benefit from the differential
in
returns.
The consequence of encouraging movements of
this kind is that there is a surge of capital flows into emerging
markets in
Asia and
It is in this light that we must view the
IMF’s optimism that comes from the fact that the emerging markets are
doing
well enough to lift “global growth”. That unevenness is not the basis
for
combined growth but for conflict that demands responses that could
undermine
the competitiveness of the emerging market economies. Moreover, the
capital
inflow surge into some of these emerging markets results in real estate
and
stock market bubbles that are likely to burst and therefore render such
growth
fragile. What is needed is a return to an effort at having a globally
synchronised fiscal push with measures to distribute the benefits of
that push
across continents and countries. It is that option that the IMF
foregoes when
it emphasises the need to “stabilise and subsequently reduce high
public debt”
and calls for “a strengthening of
private demand in advanced economies” without explaining how that is to
be ensured.