People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
38 September 19, 2010 |
The
Early
Kalidasa Syndrome
Utsa Patnaik
THE most valuable resource
that a
country has is its people. The poor are not a liability, but an asset;
they are
the producers of essential goods and services we use, they hold up the
sky for
us for a pittance of a reward. The least that a country can do is to
ensure
that its people get enough to eat, that already low nutritional
standards are
not compromised. The present government has achieved a dubious record:
the
level of per head cereal supply and consumption in
Cereals account for
nine-tenths of
food grains, which provide three-quarters of both energy intake and
protein
intake for the average consumer. Average calorie intake and protein
intake have
both fallen since 1993. The fall in per head food grain supply and
consumption
is not new, it has been going on for over a decade, yet our leading
economists
and policymakers have contributed to increasing food insecurity by
their
refusal to remove the artificial barriers to distribution created by
arbitrarily dividing the population into ‘below' and ‘above' poverty
line.
They remain as unmoved as
Kalidasa
proverbially hacking away at the very branch on which he sat — they
would
rather let food grains rot than feed the poor. What explains this
torpor, this
near-comatose lack of response to a long-brewing crisis of increasing
hunger?
The answer is that they simply fail conceptually to recognise that
hunger is
growing because of the serious misconception they have regarding the
behaviour
of cereal demand in a developing economy.
ILL-ADVISED
POLICIES
John Maynard Keynes had
remarked that
the world is moved by little else but ideas. Once a wrong idea gets
into the
head of a policymaker it is very difficult to get it out. Keynes's
argument on
the paradox of thrift — if every person saves more, the nation ends up
saving
less — is still not understood 75 years after the General Theory and
finance ministers
continue to behave like housewives, cutting back spending to balance
budgets
even though they have to deal with rampant unemployment. Many
ill-advised
policies we see creating havoc around us arise from incorrect but
obstinately
held ideas.
The crucial incorrect idea
here is
that there is nothing surprising about cereal consumption falling — as
a
country develops and its per head income rises, people diversify their
consumption away from ‘inferior' cereals and towards ‘superior' food,
including
milk, eggs, meat, and so on. Most economists thus believe in what they
call a
‘negative income elasticity of cereal demand' and this influences many
others,
so they actually interpret declining grain consumption in a positive
light.
Their idea however arises from ignorance and is factually incorrect. It
represents a fallacy of composition, in which only a part of total
cereal
demand — that directly consumed (as boiled rice, chapatti and so on) —
is taken
into account and cereal demanded as livestock feed converted to milk,
eggs,
meat, and so on is ignored.
Fifty years of data from
the United
Nations Food and Agriculture Organisation show that as average income
rises in
a country and diets become more diversified to superior foods, the per
head
cereal/food grain demand far from falling rises steeply, and average
calorie
and protein intake rise in tandem. This happens because much more
cereals get
consumed indirectly as feed converted to animal products.
The higher the average
income of a
country, the higher is its cereal consumption and the higher the share
of the
latter, which is indirectly consumed, as the Table shows. The richest
country
in the world, the
China has been raising its
income
fast — we are talking of purchasing power parity adjusted US dollars —
and by
now it converts a massive 115 million tonnes of cereal output as feed
to animal
products, compared with less than 10 million tonnes in India. Its
people
consume directly as much as Indians do, but owing to more diversified
diets
they consume nearly 300 kg cereals per head, 115 kg more than we do and
their
average calorie and protein intake is higher.
Why has
Krugman et al did not take
account of
the adverse changes in income distribution, owing to severely income
deflating
fiscal policies advised by the Bretton Woods Institutions and
faithfully
implemented by successive Indian governments after 1991, which sent
agriculture
in particular into a depression from which it has still not recovered.
With
unemployment rising, with the fruits of growth going to a tiny minority
while
the masses suffered income deflation, the effects of dietary
diversification by
the rich have been swamped by an absolute decline in cereal intake for
the
majority.
National Sample Survey
(NSS) data
show for all except two states an absolute fall in average animal
products
intake as well, along with falling direct cereal intake over the
reforms
period. No wonder average energy and protein intake have both fallen.
People
other than the rich are not diversifying diets; even the hungry are
forced to
cut back and are suffering nutritional decline.
By 2008, the situation was
even worse
despite good output. A record 31.5 million tonnes of food grains were
exported
plus added to stocks, reducing domestic cereal supply steeply to 156 kg
per
head. This happened because the global recession impacted to raise
unemployment
and food prices spiralled to lower real incomes, so that there was a
fresh
round of loss of purchasing power.
TIMID &
RELUCTANT
HALF-MEASURES
What is to be done? Bold
measures are
required, not the timid and reluctant half-measures we see. The Mahatma
Gandhi
National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS) needs to be
seriously
implemented to raise purchasing power and extended to urban areas that
have
seen a steep rise in poverty. For example, in
Food distribution through
the PDS
should be universal, freed from targeting, from the shackles of
arbitrary and
incorrect official poverty estimates. The recent decision to do away
with
targeting only in some districts will help very little. The government
wishes
to restrict the food subsidy but fails to realise that a version of the
paradox
of thrift operates here as well — the more it tries to reduce subsidy
by
restricting access, the more the subsidy will rise uselessly to finance
holding
unsold food stocks as now.
This country can afford to
feed all
its people at a decent level — what is holding it back is not lack of
resources
but ignorant and incorrect ideas. Will the economists at the highest
levels of
policymaking abjure dogmas and think the problem through rationally? Or
will
they inflict more punishment on the people, subjecting this country to
the
shame of falling even further behind the least developed countries and
(Sub-headings
have been added)