People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
37 September 12, 2010 |
Commons
as an Active Producer
Prabir
Purkayastha
TODAY,
the new digital age is recreating a number of much older ideas.
Producing
software collaboratively and with various free software licenses is
building a
new digital commons. This is not all. We also have the Wikipedia, which
at
least in less politically contended areas, has produced a new
encyclopaedia,
again built collaboratively. Music, films and various other forms,
earlier
regarded distinct from software, are also in the process of discovering
the new
world where copyright rules only in the courts and cannot be maintained
in the
real one. It is this new age of knowledge, creativity and software
commons that
is confronting the old world of “intellectual property”.
The
idea that private property is integral to economic production assumes
that
without property, production will come to a grinding halt. It is this
deifying
the current form of capitalist property that we need to demolish. Eben
Moglen,
in his talk in
There
are significant similarities between the earlier enclosure of the
commons and
the current enclosure; as well as dissimilarities. The earlier commons
enclosed
were passive and limited. The forests, common lands, water bodies, all
provided
humanity with food and other resources. With the development of private
property, these commons were gradually enclosed, for example, the
colonial
enclosure of forests in
FENCING
COMMONS
The
attempt to create “intellectual property” in software and life sciences
is
another attempt to fence in what was earlier regarded as belonging to
commons.
Earlier, mathematics and algorithms were thought to be non-patentable
as was
all life forms. Today, software is sought to be patented as is genetic
code.
The current patent regime in the
The
significant difference between the commons of yore and the current
commons is
that the earlier commons were finite, even if they appeared as
relatively
infinite. Land was always a limited resource, but it is clear today so
is air
and water. While fencing in of the commons to create property helped
the rich
and the powerful, it could still be argued that this was “more
economically
efficient”. This is the argument that is advanced by a host of
economists who
talk about the tragedy of the commons – that commons not being
anybody's
private property, gets over-exploited. Therefore the “need” to fence it
in and
exploit it privately as a more economically efficient form of
production.
This
has also produced a lot of literature regarding the tragedy of the
anti-commons, showing that rules of the commons do work quite well, and
fails
only under some conditions. But even if we disregard this literature,
the key
difference between the earlier finite commons and the current knowledge
commons
– science, software, mathematics – is that they are not finite. A
software or a
scientific law, used again and again does not wear out – you cannot
over-exploit these commons. They are infinite human resource.
This
brings us to the next question. If human production is indeed
increasingly
knowledge based, is there a contradiction in the way it is being
produced and
the way goods are produced? If we look at production of goods, it is
still
dominated by economies of scale, particularly the metallurgical and
energy
industries. Despite all the technical innovation involved, the
technology in
these areas is still as it existed in the last 100 years.
In other areas, there is a real possibility
of de-scaling technology, even if it is in its infancy. For the time
being, we
can still accept that though economies of scale do not work so well in
a range
of goods, it is still the dominant form of production of material
goods.
The
scene is radically different if we take the production of knowledge
itself. The
20th century saw the rise of scientific research being
corporatised
in a big way. Huge research laboratories were what big corporations set
up –
Bell Laboratories being of course the leading example. But this was not
an
exception. The 20th century saw the role of individual
innovators
reduce and the rise of big corporate research centres.
ECONOMIES
OF NETWORKS
However,
by the end of the 20th century, the economies of scale in
producing
knowledge that led to the setting up these laboratories had
disappeared. What
we have today are economies of networks. A set of people working
independently
have written 204 million lines of source code, producing
what is known as Gnu/Linux operating system.
For just the kernel alone (the part that
really drives the CPU hardware), 3,200 developers from 200
companies and
over a 100 countries have contributed for the current release. This is
the
power of network that no economies of scale can give within a company,
however
large it might be. It is this power of the network that is creating the
new
digital commons.
Most
people have who have focussed on copyright and patents miss one central
point
in this. Copyright and patents give rights over copies or rights over
reproduction. What is fundamentally changing is the mode of production
of
knowledge, and this is qualitatively different from what we have seen
earlier.
This
is what Eben in his talk called the active commons. Commons by virtue
of
producing new “goods” is forcing even large corporations to adopt free
and open
source software – not because they want to but because they can no
longer
compete with this form of production. IBM did not set out to promote
open
source software, that it does is because it sees in this a superior
model of
producing software and would like to piggy-back on it for its business.
This
is no longer restricted to software. The phenomenon of copyrighted
music
distributed by music labels is giving way to free distribution through
peer to
peer sharing. But this is only the first step. The music world is
moving from
distribution monopolies to concerts being the major money maker. In
Film
making is also undergoing a major change. Both in distribution and in
film
making, the role of the studios are dwindling. Yes, there is still the
block-buster movies with huge budgets. But it is also possible to
produce films
with much less costs and distribute directly. Economies of scale are
breaking
down here as well, though not as obviously as in music.
Eben
raised the issue what happens if we get a production system that is
based on
nano technologies at the atomic level shaping goods. Will such
techniques of
micro production make economies of scale obsolete? He passionately
believes it
will, as knowledge and the economies of networks will drive this form
of
production. In such a world, economies of scale will give away to
collaborative
networks creating new goods the same way we develop software. And if
economies
of scale disappear, so will the dinosaurs of today – large, centrally
controlled, hierarchically structured corporations that are central to
the
capitalist mode of production.
A
part of this phenomenon is already
visible. In the developed economies, particularly the US, the large
manufacturing companies have given way to companies that live off
copyright and
patents – big pharma, software and media companies. Or deal with
re-distribution of the surplus – the financial companies that produce
nothing
and just skim off the top. Already, the producers are quite often the
small
producer – either an ancillary or sometimes producing the product
itself under
a big corporation brand. The breakdown of the economies of scale is
already
under way in a number of different ways. Even without Eben's vision of
atomic
scale production of goods using nano technologies. Whether it will
extend to
all spheres of production still remains to be seen, but the demise of
large,
vertically integrated monopolies are visible over a range of
industries.
One
can argue that Eben does not address the politics of capital – that
even if a
property form is dying – its physical reach and control can be
enormous.
Capital is quite capable of taking the notion of Madam Pompadour,
“After me,
the deluge” much further. After all, French Revolution confronted an
aristocracy with rather limited fire power. Today's defender of capital
come
armed with nuclear weapons and drones for remote kills.
But
that is missing the point. If a system of production is becoming
obsolete, no
amount of fire-power can stop this change. The real question is whether
the
movement from commons to property is really being reversed today? Even
if this
phenomenon is small, is it growing and does it therefore pose a threat
to
private property? After all, when Marx wrote his Communist
Manifesto and described the enormous expansion of
production that capitalism was bringing in, capitalism was actually in
its
infancy. What was prophetic in Marx's vision is that he saw capitalist
production, not as it existed then, but as it was becoming. And this is
what we
have to see today. Not the existing form of production as it is today
but what
it is becoming. The active commons creating new knowledge and as an
agent of
breaking down the older forms of production.
The
key to the control of capital over production has been its ability to
create
continuously new knowledge and technology. Its ability create new
knowledge
that has given big capital its edge over other forms of production. It
is here
at the heart of capital that creation of new knowledge and technology -- the active commons -- is emerging. This is
the active commons driven by the collective brain power of humanity. If
capital
can no longer control the production of new knowledge, it loses control
over
technology. Its use of WTO and TRIPS – creating a larger domain of
“intellectual property” -- shows not its strength but its weakness. It
is its
inability to control the physical process of knowledge creation that it
now
seeks to control it through legal means. That is why this new form of
collaborative knowledge creation spells the doom of capital, even if
its death
throes are going to be long and painful.