People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
31 August 01, 2010 |
KERALA
CHIEF MINISTER AT NDC MEET
Growth
Strategy is Flawed, Needs Complete Replacement
Below we reproduce the
text of the speech the chief minister of Kerala, V S Achuthanandhan,
made at
the National Development Council (NDC) on July 24, 2010. Subheadings
have been
added.
THIS meeting
of the
National Development Council is taking place at a time when the entire
capitalist world is engulfed in a crisis reminiscent of the Great
Depression of
the 1930s. The Indian economy has been somewhat insulated from this
crisis,
largely because its integration into the world of globalised finance
has been
restricted till now. The union government has cause to thank the
opponents of
its neo-liberal policies for this.
POOR
PRICE
PERFORMANCE
But this is
not the only
contrast between
The union
government
assures us that inflation will come to an end soon. But the crucial
question
is: when inflation comes to an end, will the level of
prices compared to the money incomes of the working people
be higher or lower than earlier? If money incomes of the working people
are
held constant, then inflation is necessarily self-limiting, since it
rectifies
the demand-supply imbalance, which caused it in the first place, by
cutting
into their demand. One cannot therefore derive much solace from the
prediction
that inflation will come to end soon, if at its end the working people
are left
absolutely worse off in real terms. Only that
inflation control will qualify as
one, which leaves the absolute living standards of the working people
unimpaired compared to what it was prior to the onset of inflation.
And
in an economy where money wages of the vast majority of the working
people are
not indexed to prices, this can be ensured only through a universal
system of
public distribution of essential commodities at fixed prices.
The key item
here is food
grains. A basic cause of the current inflation is the precipitous
decline in
per capita availability of food grains that has occurred in recent
years. Against a
population growth rate of 1.4 per cent, the growth rate of food grains
during
1993-94 to 2003-04 was only 0.69 per cent, which further declined to
0.32 per cent
during 2004-05 to 2009-10. the per capita output, in short, has been
declining
for several years now. But what is even more bizarre is that as
inflation has
been gathering momentum, the union government has not only been
exporting
substantial amounts of cereals but also been accumulating a vast amount
of food
stocks. During 2007 and 2008,
UNCONVINCING
POVERTY
FIGURES
The mid-term
appraisal’s
claim, on the basis of the Tendulkar committee report, about declining
poverty
during the nineties, is unconvincing for this very reason. If “poverty”
is
estimated to be declining in the midst of growing hunger, then
something must
be wrong with that definition of “poverty.” All over the world, as
people
become better off, they absorb larger amounts of food grain per capita,
taking
direct and indirect absorption (via processed food and feedstock for
animal
products) together. If per capita absorption in
To control
food price
inflation, to reverse the decline in the per capita absorption of food
grains,
to ensure that stocks do not accumulate uselessly as people go hungry,
it is
essential to move to a system of universal public distribution of food
grains.
The amount given should be 35 kilograms per family per month at the
rate of Rs 2
per kilogram. The Food Security Bill, currently under discussion, must
ensure
this. This may require an additional food subsidy, over its current
level, of
not more than Rs 50,000 crore, which is less than one per cent of GDP,
and
quite manageable. It will require an increase in food grain output, but
in any
case this is essential for the future survival of our country, though
this need
has been lost in the euphoria over the growth rates. Drawing
distinctions
between the above poverty line (APL) and below poverty line (BPL)
categories in
the presence of such pervasive incidence of hunger undermines the goal
of food
security.
UNJUST
LEVY
ON
CONSUMERS
The union
government has
not only held on to burgeoning food stocks in the midst of the current
rampaging inflation, but has even chosen this very moment to raise the
prices
of petrol, diesel, kerosene and cooking
gas. This price hike is sought to be justified by it by creating the
impression
that the petroleum sector is a loss-making one; that this loss is
because the domestic
prices of petro products have been kept fixed while the world price of
crude
has increased; and that this sector survives on large government
subsidies
which cannot be sustained for long. This impression is completely
erroneous.
Nearly 51 per cent of the price of petrol and 30 per cent of the price
of
diesel consists of taxes that accrue to the union government’s
exchequer; apart
from these, substantial profits of the public sector companies like Oil
This levy
will hurt the
poorest segments of the nation’s population. For instance, the
fishermen of
Kerala, who earn on average an annual income of Rs 15,000-20,000 on
which they
have to support entire families, and who risk their lives daily for
earning
this pittance, will be crippled by the diesel price hike. So when union
government spokesmen sometimes defend the hike by using an alternative
argument, namely that it would reduce subsidies to companies and
release funds
for building much-needed schools and hospitals, and thereby obliquely
suggest
that the hike will pinch only the companies and not the final users,
they are
being disingenuous.
The hike in
prices,
moreover, is part of a policy of making petro product prices free to
move with
international prices. The world price of crude, which is the basic
input for
all petro products, is subject to very wild swings because of the
operation of
speculative forces. It was around 140 US dollars per barrel just a few
months
ago and is now nearly half that price. If our petro product prices are
linked
to the international market, then they too will be open to huge
fluctuations.
And if the farmers are to get remunerative prices, then their prices
too will
have to move up and down synchronously with crude prices, since petro
products
figure prominently among their inputs. And if such movements are
reflected in
the market prices of food grains (including even the issue prices under
the
PDS), then the consumers will be facing wild fluctuations in the prices
of most
of the essential commodities for subsistence. They will survive in
years when
speculators are bearish, but perish in years when they are bullish.
Even the
colonial
government, though belatedly, after the Bengal famine had carried off
four
million victims, had woken up to the fact that the free market should
not be
allowed to function in food grains, that food grain prices had to be
controlled
and rationing resorted to for distributing a minimum amounts of it. But
if food
grain prices are to be kept under control, then a whole range of prices
of
major inputs needed for food production and food distribution, among
whom petro
products must figure prominently, must also be kept under control. It
is
ironical that the union government should rediscover the virtues of the
free
market in such essential commodities almost two-thirds of a century
after the
colonial government had abandoned its faith in it in the wake of a
horrendous
famine. The honourable petroleum minister has given the assurance that
in the
event of such fluctuations the government will take appropriate
countermeasures
to control the prices. But, why should such a situation be allowed to
arise in
the first place?
UNHEALTHY
PRECEDENT
The
government of Kerala
earnestly requests the union government to rescind the petro product
price hike
and to abandon its policy of linking the domestic petro product prices
to the
international market. What the country needs above all is stability in
the
prices of basic goods and their insulation from wide fluctuations of
the sort
that occur in the international commodity markets.
The union
government has a
number of flagship programmes in social sectors, which are operated as
centrally
sponsored schemes. State governments have been opposed to the idea of
centrally
sponsored schemes for a long time and have demanded, instead, that the
sums
spent on these schemes should be handed over to the states to spend in
accordance with their own specific requirements, rather than on some
uniform
“one-size-fits-all” basis. The union government has not only ignored
this
request, but is now making available under these schemes large sums of
money
directly to various agencies in the state, bypassing the state
government
budget. This erodes accountability and sets an unhealthy precedent.
Moreover, it
has now
started a practice which is likely to be detrimental as much to state
finances
as to the development of the social sector itself. It often starts a
centrally-sponsored
scheme and gets state governments to fall in line and commit their plan
resources to meet their share of the cost, and then it suddenly decides
unilaterally
to drop the scheme, or to modify the scheme, or to raise the state
government’s
share in financing it. The state governments, therefore, having got
involved in
a scheme in whose formulation they had no say in the first place, are
then made
responsible for it to ever greater degrees at the whim of the centre.
They are
thus made to act as “bonded carriers” of the centrally devised schemes.
This is
an encroachment on their freedom, a pre-emption of their plan resources
against
their will, and does no good ultimately to the social sectors.
I shall cite
just two
examples. Against the pleas of most of the chief ministers at an
earlier
meeting of this very august body, the union government decided
unilaterally to
reduce its share in Sarva Shiksha Abhiyan (SSA) and raise the share of
the
state governments. Thus, the SSA, which began with 15 per cent state
government
contribution in 2001-02, and kept this ratio at 25 per cent till
2006-07, has
raised it to 35 per cent in 2007-08 and 2008-09, 40 per cent in
2009-10, 45 per
cent in 2010-11, and 50 per cent in 2011-12. As a result, the state
governments, who could otherwise have formulated schemes of their own,
keeping
their own specific requirements in mind, now find themselves
shouldering an
ever increasing burden, whose magnitude is determined again by the
centre
unilaterally, in a scheme that is not their own and into which they
entered in
the first place at the insistence of the centre. True, the thirteenth
Finance
Commission has provided grants to enable states to meet the rise in
their
obligation, but the cognisance of the problem by the commission only
underscores its seriousness. Likewise, under the National Rural Health
Mission
(NRHM) in Kerala, a number of appointments were made earlier. Now the
union
government has decided to restrict the NRHM funds exclusively for
health
infrastructure and the payment for all appointees has devolved suddenly
upon
the state exchequer. The flagship projects, in short, have become
devices for
leading state governments up the garden path.
KERALA’S
PLEA
The Kerala
government has
consistently criticised flagship programmes of the centre like the
JNNURM which
impose “conditionalities” on the states. But even benign looking
flagship
programmes like the NRHM and SSA involve an encroachment on the states’
rights,
and need to be negated.
The Right to
Education
Act, a positive step despite its lacunae, is going to place a further
burden on
the state governments. The amount made available by the thirteenth
Finance
Commission covers only 15 per cent of the estimated recurring
expenditure under
the SSA over the next five years, which is a paltry sum compared to
what is
required. The union government must take full responsibility for
financing the
implementation of the RTE Act, with states’ contribution limited to
some
“normal” projections based on base-year figures.
On the other
hand, we find
that central clearance for projects of interest to the state
governments takes
an inordinately long time. I shall cite a few examples from Kerala. The Kochi Metro Rail project, a joint
enterprise of the central and state governments, along the lines of the
DMRC,
still awaits Planning Commission’s clearance. And the Palakkad rail
coach
factory, for which the state government has met its obligation by
acquiring the
land, inexplicably finds no mention in the current year’s union budget.
The
cause of delay, in many cases, is the centre’s insistence on the PPP
mode. This
is a further encroachment on the freedom of the state governments:
while PPP can
be one of several modes from which the optimum is to be chosen, it
cannot be
simply prioritised in an arbitrary manner over all others.
Let me
conclude with a
general observation. The point of departure of the eleventh five year
plan was
“inclusive growth.” This was an admission of the fact that the benefits
of
growth did not automatically “trickle down” to the working people, and
that an
effort was needed on the part of the state to redistribute these
benefits more
evenly. Several steps have no doubt been taken by the state in this
direction.
But if, notwithstanding these, the people of India are hungrier today
than ever
before in the last fifty-seven years, then the conclusion is
inescapable --- that
the growth strategy itself must be fundamentally flawed, which requires
not
corrective measures but complete replacement, so that the basic
inequalising
tendencies which neo-liberalism unleashes are kept in permanent
abeyance.