(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India
(Marxist)
Vol. XXXIV
No.
27
July
04,
2010
Oil Price
Manoeuvres
C P Chandrasekhar
IN a show of bravado, the prime minister Manmohan Singh has declared
that the free pricing scheme announced recently for petrol would be
applied to diesel as well. This makes clear that the policy on pricing
of petroleum products had been decided and what occurred a few days
back was a well- planned manoeuvre. Not having got an adequate traction
from the Rangarajan Committee report on the pricing and taxation of
petroleum products and not wanting to lose the opportunity of pushing
ahead with petroleum price decontrol under a government not dependent
on Left support, UPA II set up an expert group chaired by former
Planning Commission member Kirit Parikh. The committee’s clear mandate
was to examine the pricing policy for four sensitive petroleum products
(petrol, diesel, PDS kerosene and domestic LPG) and recommend a viable
and sustainable pricing strategy for these products. The composition of
the committee suggested that it was expected to recommend wholesale
liberalisation of the pricing of petroleum products. The expert group
did not disappoint, and delivered its recommendations in a period of
five months. What is surprising is that the government has
decided to accept most of the committee’s recommendations and hike the
prices of petrol, diesel, kerosene and LPG, opt for price decontrol for
petrol immediately and announce that a similar transition would follow
for diesel in the not too distant future.
SURPRISING MOVE
The move is especially surprising because persisting inflation is
already a major cause for concern. The Wholesale Price Index (WPI)
figures for May pointed to three worrying trends. First, for the fifth
month running, the aggregate annual rate of inflation as reflected in
the month-on-month increase in the WPI was near or well above
double-digit levels. The figures for May put inflation at 10.2 per cent
over the year. Second, the current inflation is particularly sharp in
the case of some essential commodities, as a result of which the prices
of food articles as a group have risen by 16.5 per cent and of food
grain by close to 10 per cent. Finally, there are clear signs that what
was largely inflation in food prices is now more generalised with fuel
prices rising by 13 per cent and manufactured goods prices by 6-7 per
cent.
The immediate and near-term impact of the oil price decisions would be
an aggravation of these inflationary trends focused on essential
commodities that currently burden the common man. Petroleum products
are consumed in some measure by all. Given the fact that these products
are universal intermediates, entering into the costs of production of a
number of goods and services, the cascading effects of the price hike
on the costs and prices of a range of commodities is likely to be
significant. With prices of essentials already on the rise, the move
threatens a return to the days when inflation was a major economic
problem faced by the country. It follows, therefore, that this is the
worst time for hikes in and the decontrol of the prices of petroleum
products.
The government claims that this was unavoidable because of the “losses”
being suffered by the oil marketing companies (OMCs). When the domestic
prices of oil products are controlled but the price of imported oil is
rising, oil marketing companies receive from the consumer less than
what it costs them to acquire the products they distribute. This leads
to what are termed “under-recoveries”, which would affect the accounts
of the oil marketing companies (Indian Oil Corporation, Bharat
Petroleum Corporation, Hindustan Petroleum Corporation and IBP) that
obtain their supplies of petrol and diesel from the refineries at
prices that equal their import price inclusive of customs duty.
According to estimates, if retail prices had not been raised,
under-recoveries by the oil marketing companies would have exceeded Rs
70,000 crore in the current fiscal year. Since this is unsustainable,
it is argued, the hike in prices and a shift out of a controlled
pricing regime is unavoidable.
The government’s argument is by no means water-tight. While
under-recoveries are a reality, they do not turn oil refining and
marketing firms into loss-making enterprises, because those firms
deliver a range of products and services, the prices of all of which
are not controlled. If, for example, even if we consider the profit
after taxes of the most important oil companies over the last ten
years, they have remained positive in all years and quite substantially
so in some. Under-recoveries are notional losses that only lower book
profits relative to some benchmark. Thus, there is little danger that
the industry would be bankrupted even if prices were kept at their
earlier levels.
There is, of course, the question of fairness. Since there are many
players involved in the industry there is no reason why
under-recoveries should affect only the books of the oil marketing
companies. The returns on net worth earned by the oil marketing
companies are far more volatile and vulnerable than that garnered by
the upstream oil companies (ONGC, OIL and GAIL). The burden should be
shared by the latter, which receive prices that more than compensate
for costs; by the central government which garners revenues in the form
of customs duties and excise duties (besides dividends from the oil
majors); and by the state governments which benefit from sales taxes.
This requires, for example, the oil refineries to offer discounts when
selling products to the OMCs and for the government to reduce the taxes
it levies on oil products in order to absorb part of the under-recovery.
The controversial question as to how the burden should be shared was
analysed by a committee headed by C Rangarajan appointed to examine the
issue. The committee spent much of its energies on the different stages
through which imported and domestic crude is converted into petroleum
products supplied to the consumer, and the cost escalation that arises
as the raw material passes through these stages. Through that analysis,
it found that the upstream oil companies (or oil companies other than
the oil marketing companies, such as ONGC, OIL and GAIL) had recorded
profits to the tune of Rs 15,600 core in 2004-05 and Rs 14,600 crore in
the first nine months of 2005-06. That the oil industry’s contribution
to the central exchequer in terms of duties, taxes, royalty, dividends
etc. rose from Rs 64,595 crore in 2002-03 to 77,692 crore in 2004-05.
That the petroleum sector alone contributed around two-fifths of the
total net excise revenues of the centre. That taking Delhi as an
example, central and state taxes amounted to 38 and 17 per cent
respectively of the retail price of petrol and 23 and 11 per cent
respectively of diesel. And that the incidence of taxes as a proportion
of the retail price in India was, higher than in the US, Canada,
Pakistan, Nepal, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka, though they were lower than
in many countries in Europe known for their higher average level of
prices. In sum, the numbers suggested that there was an adequate buffer
to shield domestic consumers from the effects of increases in
international prices, so long as segments that can afford to take a cut
in petroleum-related revenues because they have alternative sources of
resource mobilisation are willing to accept such a reduction.
MOVE FAVOURING PRIVATE COMPANIES
Thus, if at all there is an argument for price deregulation, it can
only be that it is for some wrong reason to expect the oil companies
and the government to bear the burden of the irrational fluctuations in
the global prices of oil. That argument too is difficult to justify.
When the industry was wholly in the public sector, the prices of oil
products were treated as one set of instruments in the tax-cum-subsidy
regime of the government. Any losses suffered by the industry or any
shortfall in funds required for investment as a result of price
regulation were to be met from resources mobilised through progressive
taxes rather than from regressive price increases. The government
should have adopted a similar approach in the current situation and
focused on rules that can and have been devised.
It needs to be noted here that oil prices have not been held constant
in recent history. Rather, the average annual increase in prices over
the last two decades indicate that the increase (16.5 per cent) has
been much higher in the case of retail prices of petrol, for example,
than in the wholesale price index for all commodities (9.3 per cent).
The common person has indeed borne some of the burden of volatile oil
prices. What the government is arguing now is that the burden of
irrational shifts in the international prices of oil should largely be
borne by the consumer, even if the burden sharing involved is extremely
regressive. In what seems an afterthought, the government has declared
in its recent pricing policy announcement that it reserves the right to
intervene in the market to protect consumers if prices rise to levels
too high or price movements are excessively volatile. Nobody can or has
taken that right from the government. It is the government that is
giving it up, and exposing the common person to the volatility in
international prices that has no rational basis.
The question remains as to why the government is choosing this policy
direction. Ideological commitment may be playing a role. But, more
importantly, the government’s move seems intended to favour the private
companies that have been allowed to enter and expand in this sector.
Private companies will treat any shortfall in profits as a “loss” and
demand price adjustments. The government seems inclined to oblige.