People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
10 March 07, 2010 |
BUDGET 2010-11: A NEO-LIBERAL
OFFENSIVE
Prabhat Patnaik
WHAT
is striking about the 2010-11 union budget is not just its class
outlook, but the class
strategy it displays. The doling out of direct tax concessions that
would
primarily benefit the upper salariat and the affluent yuppies,
even as food and fertiliser subsidies are cut and petrol
and diesel prices are jacked up, and that too in the midst of an
inflationary
upsurge in food prices the like of which the country has not seen since
1974-75, is a clear signal that the Manmohan Singh government is
attempting to
enlist the support of the affluent urban middle classes to advance its
neo-liberal agenda, and has no qualms about squeezing the people under
its
juggernaut. Till now it had been �fettered� by its dependence upon the
support
of the Left; now it feels free to push the neo-liberal agenda, so dear
to
corporate and financial interests, and has worked out a class strategy
for
doing so.
There
is an eerie resemblance here to the class strategy of Margaret
Thatcher. She
had viciously attacked the working class, smashed the trade unions,
pushed up
unemployment to over two million, and had steeply escalated income and
wealth
inequalities in
The
government of course pretends that this budget too is for the aam aadmi; but that only shows the
richness of its sense of irony. To claim that persons earning lakhs of
rupees
per year, who are the beneficiaries of direct tax concessions,
constitute the aam aadmi, while the fisherman who
risks
his life daily by venturing out to the sea for an annual income of less
than Rs
20,000, and who will be hit hard by the diesel price hike, does not, is
to
display supreme irony.
There
was a time when even as the government increased petrol prices, it
would spare
diesel prices, since diesel and kerosene prices were linked for
technical
reasons, and raising the former would necessarily raise the latter, to
the detriment
of the poor. But such reticence no longer prevails. Diesel prices have
been
raised and kerosene prices will follow, but the government does not
care.
Indeed, a whole lot of petro-product prices are going to be raised as a consequence of the increase in
import duty, i.e. a new round of price increases on top of
what Pranab Mukherji has announced is in the offing. And
if the Kirit Parikh Committee�s absurd recommendations for linking
domestic
prices to world prices, absurd because that would mean importing the
massive
speculation-induced world oil price fluctuations into the domestic
economy, and
hence making the domestic price-level a yo-yo in the hands of
international
speculators, are accepted (they are being examined by yet another
government committee),
then the petro-product prices will be jacked up even further in the
coming
months.
Mukherji�s
argument for raising the import duty on petroleum and the central
excise duty
on petrol and diesel is particularly specious. Since petrol prices had
not been
raised adequately even when world crude prices had crossed $130 per
barrel, the
government, he argues, has somehow earned the right to raise the prices
now.
The current price hike, he contends, is a reward for the government�s
earlier
abstinence, which is ridiculous since it is not as if petrol prices had
been lowered earlier and are now being
restored to pre-lowering levels. Besides, the biggest component of
petrol and
diesel prices in the country consists of government taxes; there is no
logical compulsion
therefore about raising taxes on this commodity.
Much
has been written and said, rightly, about the �cascading effect� of the
higher
taxes on petrol and diesel, which would raise the prices of these
commodities by
close to Rs 3 per litre. What is striking
about Mukherji�s budget however is the complete lack of concern not
just about
the inflationary implications of this particular move, but about
inflation in
general. Just the day before the presentation of the budget,
parliament had
discussed the price issue and several members had asked the government
to use
the PDS to combat inflation. Indeed this is so obvious a panacea that
it should
not need labouring. Since the food price rise, even by the government�s
own
admission, is because of supply shortages (even if these shortages are
artificially compounded by hoarding and speculation), the immediate
move must
be to throw government-owned surplus foodgrain stocks (i.e. actual
stocks minus
the minimum buffer stocks), which currently exceed 27 million tones (as
on
January 2010), on the market. These
stocks obviously cannot be thrown on the open market,
since speculators would then buy up these stocks
gleefully, as had happened in 1972-73, and hence blunt their
anti-inflationary
impact; they have to be released through the public distribution
system. This is the only, immediate, and effective
way of tackling food price inflation. But the government has no
intention
of doing this. The fact that the food subsidy in the budget is lower
than for
2009-10 by over Rs.400 crores, suggests that the government intends
neither to
sell these stocks through the PDS, nor merely to hold on to them (for
either of
these options would have raised the food subsidy, the latter because of
higher
interest payments), but rather to do precisely what it should not do,
namely to
sell these stocks in the open market, which means that it is not over
much
concerned about inflation.
In
fact Mukherji said as much in his post-budget TV interview. He made the
point
that his way of combating inflation was by augmenting supplies in the
long-run,
for which he claimed to have taken steps in the budget, such as
earmarking Rs 300
crores for 60,000 �pulses and oilseeds villages�, and Rs 400 crores for
extending the �Green Revolution� to the eastern region of the country.
(These
amounts of course are too trivial to make any difference, but let us
ignore
that for the moment). As for short-run measures, these according to him
were
unnecessary, since the inflation rate was coming down anyway!
The
logical fallacy, indeed the chicanery, behind the argument about
inflation
coming down, is often not appreciated. Inflation,
precisely when it hurts the people, is essentially a self-limiting
phenomenon.
Inflation can be categorised into two kinds: that caused by excess
demand and
that caused by �cost-push�. A cost-push inflation arises when some
input cost
(or excise duty as in the present case) rises, which is �passed on� in
the form
of higher prices; in response to this initial price rise, money wages
rise,
which in turn is passed on in the form of still higher prices, and so
on. As
long as each component of price keeps rising with the rise in the
price, to ensure that its share in total value does
not decline, the price rise continues ad
infinitum. But if some cost element, typically the wage cost, does
not rise
in tandem with the price, then inflation eventually comes to a halt.
But this
also means that the real wage rate comes down because of a cost-push
inflation,
and this coming down is the reason for the end of cost-push inflation.
Much
the same can be said of excess-demand-caused inflation. Such inflation
gets
eliminated when someone�s demand is curtailed, and typically that
demand is
curtailed where the money incomes of some buyers do not go up as prices
rise,
i.e. where the money incomes are not indexed to prices. This is
typically true
of the working people, especially of the vast mass of unorganised
workers.
Precisely because their incomes are not indexed to prices, inflation
hurts
them, and eventually comes to an end by
squeezing them.
In
Latin American countries where inflation rates in the past have quite
often
been quite phenomenal, the reason lies in the fact that wages in such
cases
have been indexed to prices. In
An
example will make this last point clear. Let us start from a situation
where
the supply of foodgrains is, say, 100 units and equals the demand at a
price of
Rupee One per unit. The wage bill in the economy is Rs 80, all of which
is
spent on foodgrains. Now, suppose supply falls to 95, so that there is
an
excess demand of 5 units at the old price. The price will rise, i.e.
inflation
will set in. If all incomes are indexed to the price-level, then this
excess
demand will never get eliminated and hence inflation will continue ad infinitum. But if wages are not
indexed but other incomes are, then inflation will come to an end when
the
price has climbed up to Rs. 16/15 (or Rs.1.07), for, at that price, the
workers
can buy only 75 units of foodgrains from their total wage bill of
Rs.80, which
means 5 units less than before; and this eliminates excess demand. So, inflation is self-limiting precisely because
the poor get squeezed by it.
Hence,
when Pranab Mukherji derives satisfaction from the fact that inflation
is
coming down, even without the government�s doing anything about it,
that
satisfaction is totally misplaced: inflation�s
coming down in this way shows precisely that the people are being
squeezed by
it. Likewise, when Pranab Mukherji claims that the effect of petrol
and
diesel price increases �will get absorbed� over time, he omits to
mention that
this absorption can occur only by squeezing the poor (as in the above
example
of cost-push inflation). Inflation�s
coming down does not mean that the world returns to its pristine state
of
happiness. This coming down itself, far from being a source of
satisfaction, should rather be a cause for concern, because
it is necessarily at the expense of the poor.
Coming
to Mukherji�s �long term measures� for raising food supplies, what
exactly
these are becomes an intriguing question. The proposed expenditures on
the
�pulses and oilseeds villages� and the extension of the Green
revolution are
too trivial to matter. The reduction in fertiliser subsidy, which will
raise fertiliser
prices, will, if anything, have a negative effect on output. The thing
he must
be pinning hopes on therefore is the opening of retail trade, which
allegedly
will help in �bringing down the considerable difference between farm
gate,
wholesale and retail prices�. We are thus back to the Ambanis and
Wall-Mart as
the panacea for the agrarian crisis! And this view is attributed to the
prime minister,
who believes that opening up retail trade will increase
competition! If the prime minister�s economics training
does not equip him to see the fallacy of the argument that bringing in
monopolists to drive out myriad petty traders will increase
competition, then
all he has to do is to ask the coffee producers of Kerala who get a
pittance
for their crop even when retail coffee prices are soaring. If he
genuinely
wants the gap between retail and farm-gate prices to close, why can he
not ask
the public sector to take on a larger role in the marketing of crops, as the various Commodity Boards used to do
before neo-liberalism prevented them from
doing so.
Farmers
however are just an excuse. Just as the World Bank used to trot out
different
arguments at different times for promoting �economic liberalisation�,
our
government trots out different arguments at different times for opening
up to
the Ambanis and Wall-Mart. Sometimes it is the consumers� interests,
sometimes
it is freedom of choice, and now it is the farmers� interest.
Dreariness
has its uses. Pranab Mukherji�s dreary speech camouflaged the major
thrust that
this budget has given to the neo-liberal agenda. (The dreariness,
unfortunately
for him, did not succeed in camouflaging the fuel price hike).
Disinvestment is
to proceed apace, and is a major contributor to the so-called
�Miscellaneous
Capital receipts� of Rs 40,000 crores, even though there is no
theoretical
argument for it. Disinvestment is
theoretically no different from a fiscal deficit: the latter puts
government bonds into non-government hands while the former puts
government
equity into non-government hands; they are only different forms
of raising finance but with identical macroeconomic effects. A
Financial Sector Legislative Reforms Commission is to be set up to
�rewrite and
clean up the financial sector laws to bring them in line with the
requirements
of the sector�. Since all government committees and Commissions are
like slot
machines where the government gets the recommendations it wants, this
Commission is the route to financial sector liberalisation. And lest
the
government does not succeed in accomplishing its cherished
liberalisation
measures through this Commission, it has a second string to its bow: a
Financial Stability and Development Council which is to be set up �to
strengthen and institutionalise the mechanism for maintaining financial
stability�. Add to all this the �opening up� of retail trade and the
allocation
of coal blocks for captive mining, and you find that in all the crucial
sectors
where the �reforms� had been thwarted, viz. public sector, financial
liberalisation
and retail trade, this budget has given a forward thrust to the
neo-liberal
agenda.
But
then what about the �massive� increase in social sector and rural
development
outlays that the budget promises? This is a chimera. Central plan
outlay on
rural development (all comparisons are BE to BE) is slated to increase
by a
mere 6.6 percent over 2009-10, which means a real absolute decline; and
MGNREGS
outlay by a mere 2.5 percent. And as for Central plan outlay on social
services,
the increase provided under the plan is significantly counterbalanced
by a
decline in non-plan expenditure in this sector. If we take the sum of
Central
Plan outlay and non-plan expenditure on social services then the
nominal
increase in 2010-11 over 2009-10 is only 12.5 percent, which in real
terms
means very little.
All
this is hardly surprising. After all, the total expenditure of the
central
government is expected to rise in nominal terms by a mere 8.6 percent,
which
means a stagnation in real terms. Within this overall stagnation, large
apparent
increases on specific items are more likely to be the results of
statistical
jugglery or reallocation rather than matters of any substance.
The
pushing of the neo-liberal agenda requires inter
alia a neutralisation of opposition from the state governments, and
this
can be ensured only if they are reduced to mendicant status. The 13th
Finance Commission, unilaterally set up by the central government, has
already
done the needful in this regard: it has kept the total share of tax
devolution
from the centre to the states at 32 per cent (up marginally from the
30.5 per cent
under the previous Commission) compared to the 50 per cent demanded by
most state
governments. And the central government can be relied upon to compress
its
loans and grants to states, to offset even such increases in revenue
transfers
that it is statutorily required to make. In the 2010-11 budget for
instance
while its statutory transfers increase by 26 per cent over the current
year,
its loans and advances rise by a mere 8.9 per cent. With such
compression, one
can be sure that the states will continue to retain their mendicant
status.
Neo-liberalism
is clearly on the offensive. But the Manmohan Singh government
miscalculates by
ignoring the fact that unlike in Thatcherite Britain, the affluent
middle class
it is wooing is a minuscule segment of society, while those squeezed by
neo-liberalism, the workers, peasants, agricultural labourers, and
petty
producers, constitute its overwhelming majority.