People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIV
No.
02 January 10, 2010 |
Oppose this
Attempt to Destroy Indian Science
Amit
Sengupta
FOR over two years the government has made
known its
intention to introduce a bill in parliament, titled: �Public Funded
Research and Development (Protection, Utilisation and Regulation of
Intellectual
Property) Bill�. The standing committee on science and technology is
presently
engaged in deliberating over the contents of the bill, and the bill is
likely
to be introduced in the next session of parliament. As the bill, if
enacted,
shall have far reaching consequences for scientific research in
The
genesis of the bill is shrouded in mystery, though there are
indications that one
major stimulant was a letter written to the government by Sam Pitroda,
chairperson
of the Knowledge Commission. A perusal of the bill suggests that it has
been
modeled on the Bayh Dole amendment of 1980 in US Patent law. Let us
start with
looking at the rationale and objectives of the bill.
In short the
bill makes it mandatory, that all forms
of IP generated through public funds, be �disclosed�, subsequent to
which the recipient
of government funding would have the choice to retain ownership of the
IP or
transfer such ownership to the government. The major impact of the bill
would
fall on research conducted in government institutions and universities,
which
are the largest recipients of public funds for research. Those entities
who
would choose to retain ownership of the IP have the freedom to transfer
the IP
to private enterprises and they also have the freedom to choose the
terms under
which such IP would be transferred. Thus a government institute can
transfer
all rights over an invention to a private enterprise through an
exclusive
licensing agreement (though it may also enter into an arrangement where
the
rights conferred are non-exclusive, i.e. it can reserve the right to
transfer
the IP to other enterprises as well).
RED
HERRING
OF THE
BAYH DOLE
AMENDMENT
However, it is important to
note, that at present
there is no bar on recipients of public funds to obtain protection for
IP
generated through such funds. This is a significant difference from the
situation that existed in the
There is
another way in which the present bill differs
from the US Bayh Dole amendment. The latter pertains only to invention,
which
means it seeks IP protection through patenting. The Indian bill seeks
protection of all forms of IP, including copyrights and designs!
Curiously, the
provisions of the bill make no sense when applied to copyrights. There
are
indications that the decision to go beyond patents, unlike in the
PUBLIC
DOMAIN SCIENCE TO
PRIVATE
MONOPOLY
OVER
KNOWLEDGE
The most important departure
that the bill seeks from
present practice, is to make it mandatory to disclose and subsequently
register
all advances in research as �Intellectual Property�. The bill is thus
an
encouragement to universities and government research institutions to
patent
all forms of research and subsequently to pass on the patents to
private
enterprises. The introduction of onerous mandatory provisions in the
bill, shifts
the
balance as regards disclosure of research findings, from largely being
in the
public domain to largely being under IP protection.
This
is not a minor departure because it incorporates not just an
administrative
step, but also a deeply ideological understanding of how innovation is
to be
promoted and how such innovation can be used for public interest. The
first
important premise of the bill is the argument that unless research is
protected
through protection of Intellectual Property, it cannot be used for
�public
good�.
Such
an understanding is reflected in the preamble, where the bill is
described as:
�A Bill to
organise,
promote, and regulate the public availability of Intellectual Property
originating from government funded research and development.� The
preamble further
states that the proposed legislation, �promotes
collaboration between government, private enterprises and
non-government organisations;
promotes commercialisation of IP generated out of government funded
R&D and
promotes the culture of innovation in the country�. Thus, the bill
is
premised on an understanding that �public availability� of the fruits
government
funded R&D is best ensured through �protection of Intellectual
Property�,
by �commercialisation of IP� and through �collaboration with private
enterprises�. These are the major operative elements of the proposed
bill.
FLAWED
UNDERSTANDING
OF
THE RESEARCH CYCLE
Unfortunately
the premise
is deeply flawed as it is located in an erroneous understanding of how
research
is done, how research is utilised and how research results in public
goods.
When scientists conduct research, they are not concerned with the IP
that is
generated at every step. This is so because the claim of Intellectual
Property
is a claim to an exclusive right and has to be based on proof that the
research
is entirely innovative, that it is not the product of already existing
facts.
The dividing line between true innovation, that produces something
entirely new,
and research that builds on known facts is often blurred, especially in
situations where emerging disciplines of scientific research involve
collaboration between different streams in the sciences.
Moreover, such
constant
urgency to identify what can be patented actually constrains rather
than
promote research. Most research that produces important results starts
as a
branching tree, with each twig giving rise to new ideas, and finally
one or
more of the branches bear fruit! Patenting at every step prevents
others from
building on ideas generated, and thus one can end up with a long stem
with one
patent, rather than a full grown tree of ideas with several novel
products.
Thus for example when attempting to find a new drug that treats
Tuberculosis,
different research teams can approach the problem from different ends.
One team
may try to locate a weakness in the cell of the bacteria while another
tries to
identify compounds that exploit the weakness and kill the bacteria. If
each
team were to patent, we may end up with two very good patents, but no
final
product as the two would not have collaborated. This problem is most
prominent
in the case of �upstream� research, that results in development of
tools for
further research of different kinds or �platforms� on which future
research can
build on. Rather than
promote
commercialisation, patents on basic research platforms constitute a
veritable
tax on commercialization.
Compulsive
patents also
lead to the generation of what are known as �patent thickets�, that is
registration of a large number of patents that restricts others from
approaching a problem by surrounding the core of the problem with
patents.
These are some
of the
real pitfalls of a research system that is designed to patent at every
step � a
system that the bill seeks to promote aggressively. The bill, thus,
clearly
falls into the trap of believing that patenting aggressively will lead
to
better utilisation of research.
Further, by
making it
mandatory to patent, the bill places onerous responsibilities on both
researchers and research institutions. Researchers could well be bogged
down
constantly by the need to file and then maintain patents. Filing a
patent is
really the first small step in IP management. The much larger,
cumbersome and
expensive part is to face off challenges to the patents, especially if
the
patents are to be filed in foreign locations as well. The bill also
talks about
making it mandatory for all institutions and universities who receive
public
funds for research to set up IP management cells. The sum of this
entire
exercise could well be that scientists and scientific institutions
spend a
major share of their time in filing and managing patents, rather than
in doing
actual research!
KNOWLEDGE
TRANSFER
NEED
NOT BE MONOPOLY CONTROL
A second
premise of the bill
is that in order for research products to be commercialised,
enterprises need
to be given exclusive monopoly right over that product. If this were
not so,
rather than the cumbersome process of patenting, placing in public
domain
research findings should suffice in promoting uptake of research by
commercial
enterprises. In fact, the conventional wisdom as regards public funded
science
has been that the fruits of such research should be placed in the
public
domain, so as to promote public goods. Public institutions were seen as
repositories of knowledge, and technology transfer arrangements with
enterprises led to the dissemination of that knowledge. The IP based
system of
knowledge transfer seeks to change this model into one where the
balance shifts
to private monopolies, who not only commercialise the products of
research but
also have monopoly control over the products. The impact this has had
on
medicine prices, and the consequence for millions of people who
desperately
need life saving medicines, is too well documented to repeat here.
Importantly,
there is no evidence that the IP based system actually leads to more
innovation
and better and larger number of useful products. The TRIPS agreement in
1995
was an attempt to create a global system that would make it easier for
drug
companies to patent, and thus hold monopoly rights. Fifteen years since
the
TRIPS agreement, the evidence suggests that this has not led to any
increase in
innovation or the uptake of research. In fact the number of really
innovative
medicines introduced in the market have declined over the past decade
and a
half.
INCENTIVISE
RESEARCH
THROUGH
ADEQUATE GUIDELINES
The third
premise behind
the bill is that it shall provide incentives to researchers to
innovate. Thus
the bill has provisions that specify the percent of income that accrues
to a
university or institution through licensing research products to
enterprises
that would be transferred to researchers. It should be understood that
most public
institutions have rules which specify just this. If the intent is to
incentivise innovation, there is no need to legislate regarding this.
Instead
the government can frame appropriate guidelines to be followed by all
public
institutions.
MIRAGE
OF
EXTRA
RESOURCES
A fourth
premise is that
licensing of research products to commercial enterprises would be a
lucrative
additional source of revenue for public funded institutions. Evidence
in this
regard from the
SCANDALOUS
MOVE
The
manner in which the bill is being pushed by the government is nothing
short of
a scandal. For a piece of legislation that could have such far reaching
repercussions
on the way scientific research is done in the country, there has not
been any
attempt to build a consensus. The scientific community is, largely,
blissfully
ignorant of how the bill can transform them from scientists to IP
managers!
Parliament must reject the enactment of this legislation. Moreover it
is the
task of all democratic forces in research institutions and universities
to
conduct a campaign to explain about the dangers that loom ahead in the
shape of
this Tughlak like attempt to
restructure Indian science.