People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIII
No.
47 November 22, 2009 |
Would
C
P Chandrasekhar
AS
the world looks to full stabilisation and a
rebound from the crisis due to the efforts of governments, it is clear
that it
is finance rather than the real economy that has benefited more from
those initiatives.
In fact, the turnaround in the financial sector, which was responsible
for the
crisis in the first instance, has been faster and more noticeable than
that in
the real economy. What is more, as the popular concern about swelling
bonuses
for financial managers illustrates, the recovery of finance is seeing a
return
to practices that generated the imbalances that underlay the crisis.
This
is not true just at the level of individual
institutions or countries, but globally as well. Thus, the financial
recovery
has resulted in a revival of capital flows to emerging markets since
March
2009, even while the flow of credit to the real sector in the developed
countries is still limited. Much of these flows are concentrated in
Asian
emerging markets that have been less adversely affected by the crisis
than
other countries, and therefore promise quick returns to a financial
sector that
is yet to write off a large volume of bad assets. The surge is clearly
feeding
on itself inasmuch as it has generated an asset price boom in recipient
countries, encouraging further speculative flows. As the International
Monetary
Fund�s Regional Economic Outlook released in October reports, �emerging
Asia �
has especially benefited from equity market inflows, which have not
only
exceeded those to other regions, but have also returned to levels
prevailing
before the crisis. External equity and bond issues by emerging Asian
economies
have also returned to pre-crisis levels, a much stronger rebound than
in other regions.
Even inflows of syndicated loans have resumed to emerging
This
turnaround is worsening an imbalance that
was seen as being a medium-term influence that triggered the crisis of
2008:
the imbalance in the distribution of global reserves. The surge in
capital
inflows to Asian emerging markets puts upward pressure on the
currencies of
these countries, which can ill-afford currency appreciation at a time
when they
are just recovering from the decline in exports that the recession
generated. Such appreciation makes their
exports more expensive in foreign currency terms and erodes export
competitiveness.
Not
surprisingly, central bankers have stepped in
to manage exchange rates and stall or dampen appreciation by buying up
dollars
and adding it to their reserves. According to the IMF, from March
through
September 2009, emerging Asian countries accumulated US$510 billion in
reserves, compared with US$69 billion in emerging Europe and US$17
billion in
When
reserves accumulate rapidly, central banks
look for liquid and safe assets. And since the dollar remains the
world�s
reserve currency and the
This
reverse flow of capital from developing to
developed countries had in the past been held responsible for the
excess
liquidity, credit and consumption in the
II
What
the recent Asian experience illustrates is
that financial rather than trade flows often generate the imbalances
reflected
in the uneven distribution of global balance of payments surpluses and
foreign
exchange reserves. If those reserves are seen as contributing to a
process that
leads to a financial and economic crisis, then the fault possibly lies
in the structures
created by the financial policies of the developed countries rather
than in the
exchange rate policies of the developing.
What
is more the revival of financial flows has
been accompanied by tendencies the full import of which has been
ignored in the
complacence generated by the recovery in
Not
surprisingly, the IMF reports that evidence for
the year since September 2008 indicates that unlike the developed
countries where
bank credit flows froze in the wake of the crisis, bank credit growth
in Asia
has only slowed and that in some cases such as China it has in fact
risen
sharply. There are many benign explanations for this, including the
strong
balance sheets of the banks that have recapitalized themselves since
the 1997
crisis and been more cautious in their practices. As the IMF puts it:
�Unlike
in Europe, Asian banks had little exposure to U.S. toxic assets, and
the rise
in domestic nonperforming loans has been modest, so the damage to their
capital
positions from the crisis has been relatively small. Moreover, they
have been
quick to replenish their buffers, raising more than US$106 billion in
capital
since fall 2008. As a result, the declines in their capital-asset
ratios have
been negligible; in some countries, capital ratios have even risen
compared
with pre-crisis levels. So as liquidity conditions improved, Asian
banks were
in a strong position to resume lending.� To this we must add the lower
leverage
in a restructured corporate sector that had burnt its fingers in 1997.
III
There is,
however, some danger. Whenever credit
remains high or surges because of easy liquidity, some of it flows into
risky
assets. This is visible in China, which was not a victim of the 1997
crisis and
had not seen restructuring of the kind noted above. The evidence
suggests that
credit growth in China has accelerated since the beginning of 2009,
facilitated
by the government�s decision to relax informal quantitative limits on
bank credit
growth as a response to the growth slowdown resulting from the
deceleration in
export growth. The resulting credit boom raised the level of net new
bank
credit by 50 percent compared with its level 2008 as a whole.
Such credit
has financed a surge in public investment
which when mandated by government is not constrained by expectations of
market
demand and profitability. But it has also hiked private consumption and
also
private investment, particularly in real estate. According to estimates
about
40 percent of the private investment undertaken in the first eight
months of
2009 went into real estate. There is reason to believe that this is
true in
other Asian countries as well, where the liquidity resulting from the
return of
capital that had initially exited the country has helped sustain a
regime of
easy liquidity and credit with low interest rates.
Needless to
say, a credit surge of this kind
encourages speculation, leads to asset price inflation and runs the
risk of
fuelling a bubble based on loans of poor quality. This not only
questions the
sustainability of the resulting recovery but makes the growth process
partially
one that rides on a bubble. As and when governments seek to reduce
their fiscal
deficits and exit from the fiscal stimulus they chose to provide, this
aspect
of the growth process could come to dominate. If that happens, Asian
growth
would increasingly take on characteristics similar to those displayed
by the
developed industrial countries in the years before the onset of their
financial
crisis with real economy expansion being driven by debt-financed
private
(particularly housing) investment and consumption. Such growth is
obviously
vulnerable, since a credit surge cannot be sustained for long without
undermining the confidence of lenders and of those willing to carry
risk on
their behalf.
It
is in this background that statements of the
role of Asia in leading a recovery need to be assessed. Even if a
revival of
domestic demand is reducing Asia�s substantially dependence on the
markets of
the developed world for its growth, that revival is based on a
combination of
debt-financed public and private expenditure. Fiscal conservatism may
reduce
the first, while the unravelling of a speculative boom may end the
second. In
which case the crisis may still be with us.