People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIII
No.
27 July 05, 2009 |
The Paradox Of Capitalism
Prabhat Patnaik
JOHN
Maynard Keynes, though bourgeois in his outlook, was a remarkably
insightful
economist, whose book Economic
Consequences of the Peace was copiously quoted by Lenin at the
Second
Congress of the Communist International to argue that conditions had
ripened
for the world revolution. But even Keynes� insights could not fully
comprehend
the paradox that is capitalism.
In
a famous essay �Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren�, written
in 1930,
Keynes had argued: �Assuming no important wars and no important
increase in
population, the economic problem may
be solved, or be at least within sight of solution, within a hundred
years.
This means that the economic problem is not, if we look into the
future, the permanent problem of the human race
(emphasis in the original).
He
had gone on to ask: �Why, you may ask, is this so startling? It is
startling
because, if instead of looking into the future, we look into the past,
we find
that the economic problem, the struggle for subsistence, always has
been
hitherto the most pressing problem of the human race� If the economic
problem
is solved, mankind will be deprived of its traditional purpose.� He had
then proceeded
to examine how mankind could fruitfully use its time in such a world.
True,
after Keynes had written there has been the second world war, but
thereafter
mankind has had six and a half decades without any �important war� of
the sort
that could interrupt what he had called the �era of progress and
invention�.
And the rate of population growth has also not accelerated to a point
that can
be considered to have invalidated Keynes� premise. And yet
if we take mankind as a whole, it is as far from solving the
economic problem as it ever was. True, there has been massive
accumulation
of capital, and with it an enormous increase in the mass of goods
available to
mankind; and yet, for the vast majority of mankind, the �struggle for
subsistence� that Keynes had referred to has continued to remain as
acute as
ever, perhaps in some ways even more acute than ever before.
To
say that this is only because not enough time has passed, that over a
slightly
longer time period Keynes� vision will indeed turn out to be true, is
facile.
The fact that the bulk of mankind continues to face an acute struggle
for
subsistence is not a matter of degree; it is not as if the acuteness of
this
struggle for this segment of mankind has been lessening over time, or
that the
relative size of this segment has been lessening over time. We cannot
therefore
assert that the passage of more time will lift everybody above this
struggle.
DICHOTOMY STRUCTURALLY
INBUILT IN CAPITALISM
Likewise,
to say that while enormous increases have taken place in the mass of
goods and
services available to mankind (the increase in this mass being more in
the last
hundred years than in the previous two thousand years, as Keynes had
pointed
out), its distribution has been extremely skewed and hence accounts for
the
persistence of the struggle for subsistence for the majority of the
world�s
population, is to state a mere tautology. The whole point is that there is something structural to the capitalist
system itself, the same system that causes this enormous increase
in
mankind�s capacity to produce goods and services, which also ensures
that,
notwithstanding this enormous increase, the struggle for subsistence
must continue
to be as acute as before, or even more acute than before, for the bulk
of
mankind.
Keynes
missed this structural aspect of capitalism. His entire argument in
fact was
based on the mere logic of compound interest, i.e. on the sheer fact
that �if
capital increases, say, 2 percent per annum, the capital equipment of
the world
will have increased by a half in twenty years, and seven and a half
times in a
hundred years�. From this sheer fact it follows that output too would
have
increased more or less by a similar order of magnitude, and mankind,
with so
much more of goods at its disposal, would have overcome the struggle
for
subsistence. The reason Keynes assumed that an increase in the mass of
goods
would eventually benefit everyone lies not just in his inability to see
the
antagonistic nature of the capitalist mode of production (and its
antagonistic
relationship with the surrounding universe of petty producers), but
also in his
belief that capitalism is a malleable system which can be moulded, in
accordance with the dictates of reason, by the interventions of the
State as
the representative of society. He was a liberal and saw the state as
standing
above, and acting on behalf of, society as a whole, in accordance with
the
dictates of reason. The world, he thought, was ruled by ideas; and
correct, and
benevolent, ideas would clearly translate themselves into reality, so
that the
increase in mankind�s productive capacity would get naturally
transformed into
an end of the economic problem. If the antagonism of capitalism was
pointed out
to Keynes, he would have simply talked about state intervention
restraining
this antagonism to ensure that the benefit of the increase in
productive
capacity reached all.
The
fact that this has not happened, the fact that the enormous increase in
mankind�s capacity to produce has translated itself not into an end to
the
struggle for subsistence for the world�s population, but into a
plethora of all
kinds of goods and services of little benefit to it, from a stockpiling
of
armaments to an exploration of outer space, and even into a systematic
promotion of waste, and lack of utilization, or even destruction, of
productive
equipment, only underscores the limitations of the liberal world
outlook of
which Keynes was a votary. The state, instead of being an embodiment of
reason,
which intervenes in the interests of society as a whole, as liberalism
believes, acts to defend the class interests of the hegemonic class,
and hence
to perpetuate the antagonisms of the capitalist system.
ANTAGONISMS IN
THREE DISTINCT WAYS
These
antagonisms perpetuate in three quite distinct ways the struggle for
subsistence in which the bulk of mankind is caught. The first centres
around
the fact that the level of wages in the capitalist system depends upon
the
relative size of the reserve army of labour. And to the extent that the
relative size of the reserve army of labour never shrinks below a
certain
threshold level, the wage rate remains tied to the subsistence level
despite
significant increases in labour productivity, as necessarily occur in
the �era
of progress and innovation�. Work itself therefore becomes a struggle
for
subsistence and remains so. Secondly, those who constitute the reserve
army of
labour are themselves destitute and hence condemned to an even more
acute
struggle for subsistence, to eke out for themselves an even more meager
magnitude of goods and services. And thirdly, the encroachment by the
capitalist mode upon the surrounding universe of petty production,
whereby it
displaces petty producers, grabs land from the peasants, uses the tax
machinery
of the State to appropriate for itself, at the expense of the petty
producers,
an amount of surplus value over and above what is produced within the
capitalist mode itself, in short, the entire mechanism of �primitive
accumulation of capital�, ensures that the size of the reserve army
always
remains above this threshold level. There is a stream of destitute
petty
producers forever flocking to work within the capitalist mode but
unable to
find work and hence joining the ranks of the reserve army. The
antagonism
within the system, and vis-�-vis the surrounding universe of petty
production,
thus ensures that, notwithstanding the massive increases in mankind�s
productive capacity, the struggle of subsistence for the bulk of
mankind
continues unabated.
The
growth rates of world output have been even greater in the post-war
period than
in Keynes� time. The growth rates in particular capitalist countries
like
But
Keynes wrote a long time ago. He should have seen the inner working of
the
system better (after all Marx who died the year Keynes was born, saw
it), but
perhaps his upper class Edwardian upbringing came in the way. But what
does one
say of people who, having seen the destitution-�high growth� dialectics
in the
contemporary world, still cling to the illusion that the logic of
compound
interest will overcome the �economic problem of mankind�? Neo-liberal
ideologues of course propound this illusion, either in its simple
version, which
is the �trickle down� theory, or in the slightly more complex version,
where
the State is supposed to ensure through its intervention that the
benefits of
the growing mass of goods and services are made available to all,
thereby
alleviating poverty and easing the struggle for subsistence.
But
this illusion often appears in an altogether unrecognizable form.
Jeffrey Sachs,
the economist who is well-known for his administration of the so-called
�shock
therapy� in the former Soviet Union that led to a veritable
retrogression of
the economy and the unleashing of massive suffering on millions of
people, has
come out with a book where he argues that poverty in large parts of the
world
is associated with adverse geographical factors, such as
drought-proneness, desertification,
infertile soil, and such like. He wants global efforts to help these
economies
which are the victims of such niggardliness on the part of nature. The
fact
that enormous poverty exists in areas, where nature is not niggardly,
but on
the contrary bounteous; the fact that the very bounteousness of nature
has
formed the basis of exploitation of the producers on a massive scale,
so that
they are engaged in an acute struggle for existence precisely in the
midst of
plenitude; and hence the fact that the bulk of the world�s population
continues
to struggle for subsistence not because of nature�s niggardliness but
because
of the incubus of an exploitative social order, are all obscured by
such
analysis. Keynes� faith in the miracle of compound interest would be
justified
in a socialist order, but not in a capitalist one.