People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol. XXXIII
No.
20 May 24, 2009 |
Finance Capital
And Fiscal Deficits
Prabhat Patnaik
ONE
of the central paradoxes in economic theory relates to the hostility
that
financial interests in a modern capitalist economy systematically
display
towards any policy of enlarged State expenditure financed by borrowing,
even
though such expenditure increases capitalists� profits and wealth.
Let
us suppose that the government undertakes a larger borrowing-financed
public
expenditure programme, and that all borrowing is from domestic sources.
Then
corresponding to the increase in government borrowing, there must be an
equivalent increase in the excess of private savings over private
investment.
Since private investment expenditure is more or less given in any
period, a
result of past investment decisions, a rise in government borrowing
creates an
equivalent increase in private savings. Since such savings depend upon
post-tax
profits (surplus), there must be a rise in post-tax profits (surplus);
and what
is more, this rise is some multiple of the rise in government borrowing.
An
example will clarify the point. If, say, one-half of post-tax private
profits
(surplus) is habitually saved, then a rise in government borrowing by
Rs 100 at
base prices will raise private surplus by Rs 200 at base prices in
order to
generate Rs 100 of private savings to finance itself. This will happen
in a
situation of less than full employment through an increase in output
and
employment, while the base prices themselves remain more or less
unchanged; in
a situation of �full employment� (supply constraint) this will happen
through
profit inflation squeezing out �forced savings� from the workers. The capitalists as a whole in other words
earn an additional amount that is a multiple of the increase in
government
borrowing.
ADDITIONAL
PROFIT
In
his book How to Pay for the War, the well-known
English economist John Maynard Keynes had called this additional profit
of the
capitalists �a booty� that fell into their lap. He was talking about
increased
government borrowing to finance war expenditure in a situation where
the scope
for raising output and employment was limited, and he was assuming that
the
whole of the additional profits accruing to capitalists was saved. In
such a
case, if government expenditure rose by Rs 100, then there would be
inflation
that would squeeze workers� consumption, and simultaneously boost
profits.
Hence, while the actual resources for meeting war expenditure came from
the
workers whose consumption was reduced by an equivalent amount, the capitalists� wealth increased by Rs 100
despite their having done nothing. It is as if the government
snatched away
Rs 100 from the workers, put it in the lap of the capitalists, and then
borrowed these Rs 100 from them. The real �sacrifice� for the war in
other
words was made by the workers, while capitalists� wealth went up
gratuitously.
The �unfairness� of this had prompted Keynes to argue that even if the
government had to snatch away Rs 100 from the workers, the capitalists
must not
be handed this amount as a �booty�, i.e. war expenditure must be
financed
through taxes.
In
Keynes� example, supplies could not be increased and hence the rise in
profits occurred
through inflation. But if supplies can be increased then larger
government
borrowing still increases the magnitude of profits, but through an
increase in output not prices. Larger
government borrowing in short invariably boosts
capitalists� profits and wealth.
WHY INSIST FOR
�SOUND FINANCE�
But
this brings us back to the question that if a borrowing-financed
increase in
government expenditure hands over a �booty� to the capitalists that is
some
multiplier (greater than or equal to one) times this expenditure
increase, then
why are the financial interests opposed to such an increase? Why for
instance
do they favour the principle of �sound finance� and insist on the
passage of
Fiscal Responsibility legislation everywhere to limit the size of the
fiscal
deficit?
One
can give certain obvious economic explanations. The first is the fear of inflation. Larger government
expenditure by raising the level of aggregate demand will cause
inflation which
will lower the real value of all financial assets, something which
finance
capital obviously dislikes. This explanation is not without weight, but
it
fails to explain why the opposition to borrowing-financed government
expenditure should persist even in the midst of a Depression when the
increase
in aggregate demand is likely to cause almost exclusive output
adjustment with
very little impact on prices.
The
same holds for the other possible economic explanation for their
opposition,
namely a fear of worsening of balance of payments and hence of a
depreciation
of the currency, which again would lower the value of financial assets,
but in
terms of other currencies. A whole lot of measures, however, ranging
from
import controls to increased external borrowing, are available to the
government that is stimulating the economy. These measures can keep the
fear of
any currency depreciation at bay. The fear of currency depreciation
therefore
cannot also be an adequate explanation.
It
follows then that economic
explanations for the opposition of finance to increased
borrowing-financed
government expenditure are inadequate. The real basis of the opposition
is political. As the Marxist economist
Michael Kalecki had once remarked, profits are not everything for the
capitalists; their class instincts too are important. And these class
instincts
tell finance capital that a proactive expenditure policy of the State,
even for
the purpose of demand management, is detrimental to the long-term
viability of
the system in general, and of the financial class in particular.
The
mythology propagated by capitalism is that the unfettered functioning
of the
system gives rise to a state of full employment where the resources are
efficiently allocated. This myth of course cannot be sustained, since
even the
most die-hard believer in the ideology of capitalism cannot deny the
real-life
existence of periodic Depressions and the virtually perennial state of
demand-constraint
that afflict the system. Depressions are usually explained in bourgeois
theory in
terms of a setback to the �state of confidence� of the capitalists. It
follows then
according to bourgeois theory that if a capitalist economy is doing
poorly then
the remedy for it lies in providing greater support and concessions to
the
capitalists so that their �confidence� will revive, and with it the
economy.
�STATE OF
CONFIDENCE�
But
if government expenditure can be used to revive the economy, then �the
state of
confidence� of the capitalists ceases to be of paramount of importance.
The
very fact of the economy�s revival will itself, if anything, bolster
their
�state of confidence�; and even if their �state of confidence� is not
revived
fully, the government can still stabilise the economy at a high level
of
employment. What is more, since the adverse effect of government
measures for
reducing income and wealth inequalities in society, like profit
taxation or
property taxation, on the �state of confidence� of the capitalists, can
be
counteracted by government expenditure, so that unemployment need not
result
from such measures, the government can adopt them with impunity. Thus a
government that can use public expenditure to sustain the level of
activity in
the economy need not bother much about the �state of confidence� of the
capitalists and hence can bring about far-reaching changes in the
system,
including, where necessary, the induction of public enterprises.
There
is no reason why such public enterprises should be any less �efficient�
than
private enterprises in an engineering sense, i.e. in terms of physical
input
use; but even if perchance they are, an economy, with public
enterprises,
functioning close to �full employment� will still have a larger volume
of goods
at its disposal for given input endowments than a free market
capitalist
economy. In short the �social legitimacy�
of capitalism gets seriously compromised by the fact that State
expenditure can
take the economy to near-full employment irrespective of the �state of
confidence� of the capitalists.
In
a modern capitalist economy the barometer for the �state of confidence�
of the
capitalists is the state of exuberance of the stock market, i.e. the
state of
euphoria of the financial interests. If State expenditure can sustain a
near-full employment level of activity in the economy, then the
exuberance of
the financial capitalists ceases to be a matter of much concern.
Governments
can pursue whatever policies they consider socially desirable without
having to
concern themselves with the impact of such policy on the exuberance of
the
financial capitalists.
True,
the maintenance of the economy at near-full employment may cause
accelerating
inflation because of the exhaustion of the reserve army of labour, but
governments, under working class pressure, may become emboldened to
attempt to
resolve such problems through even more radical measures, such as
prices and
incomes policies, nationalisations, workers� management of factories
etc. Once
the �state of confidence� of the capitalists is given the short shrift,
then
there is nothing to prevent the economy�s ideological �slide� to
radical social
engineering and even to socialism.
DIRECT BEARING
ON RECOVERY
It
is vital for finance capital therefore that the ideological weight of
the
proposition that the �state of
confidence� of the capitalists is crucial for the well-being of society
is
not diminished one iota, for which the proposition that State
expenditure can
boost employment with impunity must be attacked, no matter how flawed
in logic
the attack may be.
This
fact has a direct bearing upon the question of recovery from the
current world
recession. The need for increasing government expenditure for
overcoming this
recession is widely recognised. And it is also recognised that it is
better for
recovery if this increase in government expenditure is coordinated
across the
major countries rather than being sequentially undertaken in an
uncoordinated
manner by individual countries.
But
no such initiatives for recovery can be undertaken because of the
opposition of
the financial interests to fiscal deficits. It is significant that at
the G-20
meeting in end-March there was no mention of any fiscal stimulus, let
alone of
any coordinated fiscal stimulus. While in the immediate aftermath of
the
financial crisis, in September and October, there was much talk of a
coordinated fiscal stimulus, that talk has died down now. True, the
By
contrast, the �bail out� package to the financial system in the