People's Democracy

(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist)


Vol. XXXII

No. 46

November 23, 2008

 

ECONOMIC NOTES

The Ongoing Industrial Recession

Jayati Ghosh


THE industrial slowdown is now accepted as fact by most policy makers and observers of the Indian economy. Yet officials and commentators seem to blame it on external factors: most obviously, the global financial crisis originating in the US economy, the consequent economic slowdown and now recession in the US, the European Union and other developed country markets, and the associated impact upon exports.


DECLINE HAS ALSO DOMESTIC CAUSES

It is certainly true that the bad news from abroad � which shows no signs of easing up � has impacted upon domestic stock markets, investor expectations, and the exporting industries in particular. But it is also unfortunately the case that our own economy has been showing several causes for concern even before that external bad news started pouring in. There was the accelerating inflation, which particularly hit food and other items of essential consumption, and recently exacerbated by the increase in petrol prices. In addition, there have been signs of decelerating growth, especially in industrial activity, and these cannot be ascribed only to reduced export orders, but are more likely to have domestic causes.

Consider the index of industrial production, presented in the chart alongside (with base year 1993-94). The general index peaked in March this year, fell quite sharply thereafter and subsequently has been more or less flat at the lower level. This pattern essentially reflects the behaviour of the manufacturing index, which accounts for around 80 percent of the weight of the general index. Such a pattern tends to be obscured by the standard way of presenting the industrial growth data, in terms of year-on-year monthly rates.

statistics


What is especially disconcerting is the evidence on electricity production, which shows hardly any increase at all but simply fluctuations around a flat trend for the past 18 months. Since electricity still remains substantially undersupplied, and its shortage can create supply bottlenecks for other production, this stagnation is worth noting.

The use-based classification industrial production suggests that the slowdown in growth is spread across several important sectors. Both basic goods and intermediate goods, which have strong backward and forward linkages with other industrial activity, have been stagnant and hardly increased at all over the past one and a half years. The production of capital goods shows much greater volatility, with a sharp increase in March 2008 but decline thereafter from that peak.


WIDESPREAD  DECELERATION

Consumer goods are the most likely --- and the first --- to be directly affected by slowing demand in domestic and export markets. This too is not a recent problem, but one which has been clearly evident in the economy at least since the beginning of the current calendar year. The production of consumer non-durable goods, which account for the bulk of consumer goods (with more than 80 percent weight) peaked in January 2008 and has fallen continuously since then. Consumer durables, on the other hand, had benefited from a credit-financed boom that had elements of unsustainability that are eerily similar to the US credit-driven consumption boom. The significant expansion of retail credit, especially credit card debt and hire purchase schemes, had generated demand for consumer durables and automobiles, but such credit-driven expansion became increasingly problematic as interest rates increased and lenders became more concerned with the viability of this rapidly growing consumer debt.

TABLE 1

Year-on-Year Growth of Index of Industrial Production

for Particular Sectors (Percent)


September 2008

Apr-Sep

2008

Food products

5.2

-1.4

Beverages, tobacco and related products

11.7

23.3

Cotton textiles

-9.3

-0.5

Wool, silk and man-made fibre textiles

1.4

-0.2

Jute and other vegetable fibre textiles (except cotton)

-0.4

-5.5

Textile products (including wearing apparel)

-1.9

3.8

Wood and wood products; furniture and fixtures

-9.7

-10.4

Paper & paper products and printing, publishing & allied industries

8.3

3

Leather and leather & fur products

-8.6

-0.3

Basic chemicals & chemical products (except products of petroleum & coal)

-3.6

6.1

Rubber, plastic, petroleum and coal products

-3.4

-4.2

Non-metallic mineral products

-0.6

0.6

Basic metal and alloy industries

5.6

6.2

Metal products and parts, except machinery and equipment

12.8

1.3

Machinery and equipment other than transport equipment

16.1

9.8

Transport equipment and parts

16.8

12.8

Other manufacturing industries

10.5

-1.1


Table 1 shows that this deceleration was widely spread across different manufacturing sectors. Indeed, only the chemicals, machinery and transport equipment sectors appear to still be growing, even if at slower rates.

What explains this trend of deceleration even before the outbreak of global financial crisis? One partial explanation can be found in the movement of imports and exports over the same period. In fact, exports have been growing throughout this period. So a fall in aggregate export demand because of the global slowdown cannot yet be blamed for the domestic inudstrial deceleration, although it may indeed have an adverse impact soon. But there has also been an explosion in imports, which suggests that import competition could have affected domestic production of many manufactured goods.


INCREASE IN NON-OIL IMPORTS

The rapidly growing import bill is only partly a result of the high oil prices that prevailed over most of 2007 and the early part of 2008. Non-oil imports also increased, aided not only by more liberalised trade but also by the appreciation of the rupee in 2007.

Table 2 shows that non-oil imports for the period April-May 2008 compared to the same period in 2007, increased by nearly a quarter. Within that, certain sectors showed very high rates of increase in import values, much more than the growth of domestic production, suggesting some amount of importa penetration in a wide range of manufacturing sectors.


TABLE 2

Increase in Import Values (in Rs Crore)

Year-on-Year for April-May 2008 (Percent)


Total imports

38.51

POL imports

73.61

Non-oil imports

23.51

Textile products, incl garments

19.28

Chemical products

56.53

Med & pharma products

37.77

Artificial resins & plastics

47.85

Metal goods

89.44

Machine tools

83.41

Non-electrical machinery

47.54

Electrical machinery

58.02

Electronic machinery

19.65

Transport equipment

25.62

Professional equipment

57.05

Other miscellaneous imports

28.95

Source: DGCI&S


This in turn suggests that the deceleration of industry may have resulted from the inability of the government to ensure the macro management of the economy in a complex global situation. The rush of foreign capital into India was acutally sought by the government, whether in the form of (subsequently fickle) portfolio investments or by encouraging Indian corporates take on more external commercial loans. This inflow led to upward pressure on the rupee, and this combined with trade liberalisation to encourage more import penetration. Some of this must definitely have damaged activity and employment among Indian producers, especially the small scale producers who still account for around one third of manufacturing GDP and much more than two thirds of manufacturing employment.

Then, the global rise in food and fuel prices was allowed to impact upon prices in India. In response to this, instead of managing these specific items, the government raised interest rates as an anti-inflationary measure. This had the effect of further damaging the prospects for industrial activity. All this happened before the subsequent outflows of captial led to a rapdily depreciating rupee --- but by then the damage had been done.

It is pointless to blame external forces for all this, because none of these processes was necessary within India. There was no need to encourage and then suffer the effects of mobile capital flows that brought in resources that were not even going to be used. Instead, capital inflows could simply have been controlled to prevent upward pressure on the exchange rate. Inflation could have been managed by first recognising the essentially speculative and therefore temporary nature of the global fuel and food price rises, and then addressing the specific management of these sectors within the economy.

Unfortunately, this previous mismanagement has worse consequences than simply the evident industrial deceleration. It has also weakened the economy even before it faces the full impact of the global recession and the financial turmoil. It is a depressing commentary on the economic management of a government that is supposedly led by economists.