People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXX
No. 19 May 07, 2006 |
Speculative
Oil Prices Benefit The US
C
P Chandrasekhar
HIGH
and rising levels of the prices of oil have stoked dormant fears of a global
economic shock comparable to those experienced in the 1970s. However, early
evidence points to a strengthening of growth in the US, despite the current
tenuous equilibrium in which global surpluses finance an ever widening US
current account deficit. The speaks for the nature of inequality within the
current global order.
As
measured by the price of West Texas Intermediate crude, that level reached $75
to the barrel on April 21, 2006 and has remained above the $70 level since. Spot
prices of Brent Crude have risen by more than 40 per over the year ending April
21. This has changed one feature characterising the oil price scenario during
much of the last decade: that high nominal prices conceal the fact that the real
price of oil is far lower than that which prevailed during the 1970s. Measured
by the Consume Price Index-deflated refiner acquisition cost of imported Saudi
Light in the US, in the years since January 1974, the recent peak real price of
oil was exceeded only during a brief period between July 1979 and February 1983.
And signs are that if current trends persist, oil producers may regain the real
price they garnered at the end of the 1979-81 shock.
Underlying
the buoyancy in prices is the closing gap between global petroleum demand and
supply at a time when the spare capacity held by Saudi Arabia is more or less
fully utilised. Global demand is estimated to rise by 1.6 million barrels per
day in 2006 relative to 2005. This trend, combined with the uncertainty in West
Asia resulting from the occupation of Iraq and the stand off in Iran over the
nuclear issue, has created a situation where any destabilising influence—such
as political uncertainty in Nigeria, the battle for control of Yukos in Russia,
civil strife in Venezuela or fears of the impact of periodic hurricanes in the
Gulf of Mexico—can trigger a sharp rise in prices.
SPECULATIVE
PRICES OF CRUDE
Exploiting
these fundamentals, speculative forces have been keeping oil demand and prices
high more recently. It is known that price trends in energy markets have
substantially increased financial investor interest since 2004, resulting in
speculative investments in the commodity. This has also affected the relative
price of oil. According to the New York
Times (April 29, 2006): “In the latest round of furious buying, hedge
funds and other investors have helped propel crude oil prices from around $50 a
barrel at the end of 2005 to a record of $75.17 on the New York Mercantile
Exchange.” According to that report, oil contracts held mostly by hedge funds
rose above one billion barrels in April, twice the amount held five years ago.
To this must be added trades outside official exchanges, such as
over-the-counter trades conducted by oil companies, commercial oil brokers or
funds held by investment banks. And price increases have also attracted new
investors such as pension funds and mutual funds seeking to diversify their
holdings. While all this means that when price expectations change the outflow
of hot money can drive oil prices sharply down, currently circumstances are in
favour of a prolonged period of high oil prices.
This
naturally has raised concerns about the possible impact of the phenomenon on
global economic performance. The immediate area of focus is on the impact it
would have on the tenuous and quirky global imbalance in which, despite a rising
current account deficit on it balance of payments, capital keeps flowing into
the US to finance that deficit. That capital flow, in turn, through its effects
initially on stock values and subsequently on interest rates and the housing
market, has increased the book value of the wealth held by Americans,
encouraging them to indulge in a debt-financed spending spree. In the event, the
US economy is growing at a remarkable (even if not healthy) rate. According to
advanced estimates released by the Bureau of Economic Affairs on April 28, US
GDP grew by 4.8 per cent in the first quarter of 2006. This is not only better
than the 3.8 and 4.3 per cent growth rates recorded in the corresponding quarter
of the previous two years, but amounts to a remarkable turn around of the
incipient deceleration in quarterly growth rates from 4.1 to 1.7 per cent
between the third and fourth quarters of 2005. What is more, the quarterly GDP
growth rate has been above 3.5 per cent in 9 out of the last 16 quarters. Not
surprisingly, Ben Bernanke, the new chairman of the US Federal Reserve, recently
told the US Congress that though high energy prices were a cause for concern in
themselves, “the prospects for maintaining economic growth at a solid pace in
the period ahead appear good.”
RESILIENCE OF
US ECONOMIC GROWTH
What
could possibly explain this resilience of US economic growth despite the fact
that the US is not insulated from the effects of rising oil prices. One factor
often offered as an explanation is the reduced dependence of the US on oil. As The Economist recently put it: “In 1980 America used a little over
17 million barrels per day (bpd) to produce GDP worth $5.2 trillion (in 2000
dollars). By last year oil consumption reached 20.7 million bpd, but GDP had
more than doubled to $11.1 trillion. As for consumers, they are not especially
dependent on petrol either. According to the BEA, in 1970, Americans spent 3.4
per cent of their consumer dollars on petrol and oil. By 1980 that rose to 5 per
cent. Yet in 2005, after a year of steadily appreciating oil prices, that number
was 3.3 per cent.”
But
this in itself is only a partial explanation, since it is not just direct US
consumption of oil which is the issue. Rising oil prices shift the distribution
of global surpluses, generating reduced current account surpluses or current
account deficits in oil importing countries and large surpluses in the oil
exporters. From the point of view of the US, the immediate impact would be a
worsening of its already widening current account deficit. Between 2002 and
2005, the ratio of the current account deficit of the US to its GDP rose by 1.56
percentage points from 4.54 to 6.1 per cent. During that period the oil trade
balance worsened by 0.92 percentage points of GDP, from 0.89 to 1.81 per cent.
Thus oil did contribute significantly to the worsening of the current account
deficit.
FINANCE OF THE
US
CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT
Further,
the US depends on flows of capital from the rest of the world to finance its
current account deficit. This process has been facilitated by the large current
account surpluses that have characterised many countries, especially in Asia,
including Japan, China, Taiwan and India. These countries, recording current
account surpluses that reflect an excess of domestic savings over investment
have invested these surpluses in dollar-denominated assets, especially US
Treasury securities. The consequence of such flows have been two-fold: initially
a boom or buoyancy in US stock markets, and subsequently a boom in the housing
market because of the depressing effect on US interest rates that large capital
inflows have had.
If
increases in oil prices reduce these surpluses and reduce the confidence of
investors from these countries in dollar-denominated assets, we should expect a
slowing of capital flows into the US and a consequent unravelling of the tenuous
global equilibrium that delivers high growth to the US. Thus, if US growth
remains robust, driven still in large part by consumer spending, then it must be
true that the above reversal of capital flows is not being realised.
Evidence
collated by the recently released World
Economic Outlook (April 2006) of the IMF suggests that this is indeed the
case. Three factors according to the IMF have facilitated this. First, a sharp
rise in the surpluses of the oil exporting countries that, as expected,
compensated for any decline in surpluses elsewhere in the world. According to
the IMF, oil-exporting countries’ export revenues have increased significantly
over the past two years, with OPEC revenues estimated at about $500 billion in
2005. Even during 2002-2004, well before the recent surge in oil prices, the
cumulative current account balances of net fuel exporters, increased by close to
90 per cent from $415 billion to $782 billion. This trend would have only
strengthened since.
SURPLUSES
RECYCLED TO THE US
What is
noteworthy is that unlike in the case of the 1970s the savings which come from
these increased surpluses have to be recycled to the US rather than through
the US to oil importing developing countries. This is because, those
countries for varied reasons, but especially a deflationary fiscal stance, have
been characterised by current account surpluses, whereas the US is characterised
by current account deficits.
This makes the recycling process, which could occur through two channels, much
simpler. One would be increased global demand from the fuel exporters, which
favours countries outside the US that are more competitive. This would further
increase their current account surpluses which would then be invested in larger
measure in the US, to finance the latter’s deficit. The other would be, for
savings to increase disproportionately in the fuel exporters, and the direct
investment of these financial savings in US paper and banks deposits. On the
surface it appears that deposits with the banks have been important, but this is
partly because flows into US paper including Treasury Bills can occur through
third country agents, such as those in London. Whatever be the route, the impact
would be to continue to finance US deficits, to sustain thereby the US dollar
and to keep interest rates depressed in the US, allowing for the continuation of
the debt financed boom for the time being.
DEVELOPING COUNTRIES THE LOSERS
The
losers would be the developing countries without surpluses on their current
account. They would experience a worsening of their deficits that would have to
be financed by high cost capital flows from the US and elsewhere.
In the event they would have to reduce their demand for dollars, if they have to
manage their balance of payments, by curtailing growth. In sum, once again the
structure of the global economy, in which the US remains the global financial
hub, seems to be working in a way that places the burden of the redistribution
of global income in favour of one section of the developing world (the oil
exporters) on other developing countries (the poorer oil importers), rather the
developed countries.