People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 35 August 28, 2005 |
A
VERY SIGNIFICANT
LEGISLATION
Parliament
Votes For Rural Employment Guarantee
Smita
Gupta
THE
passage of the historic National Rural Employment Guarantee Act by parliament is
of immense significance, in itself and in the context in which it has been
enacted. It is a fantastic challenge to the march of global finance. Given its
dissonance with the neo-liberal expenditure cutback policies of deflation, its
implications for the resistance to globalisation is huge. Its
impact will definitely reverberate the world over, inspiring social activists,
mass organisations and Left parties to form alliances and resist the anti-poor
policies of reform. Employment guarantee as a part of a constitutional
right to work has been a long-standing demand of the Left movement in India,
comprising the working poor and their mass organisations and the present Act is
an outcome of their struggles. Its genesis is rooted
in the electoral upset in 2004 in which the people rejected NDA for its
neo-liberal economic policies. Recognising the underlying rural distress and
imperative to provide assured minimum days of wage-employment, the UPA promised
in its National Common Minimum Programme (CMP) to immediately enact a National
Employment Guarantee Act. All those who campaigned and fought
for passage of this Bill deserve credit.
The
process has by no means been an easy one, with the original NAC draft facing
severe dilutions, requiring the resistance of the Left parties to push for
several key correctives for a full-fledged employment guarantee. No less
significant was the role of mass organisations and activists who launched a
nationwide campaign on the issue. The synergies that developed between NGOs,
social activists and Left parties were unprecedented and extremely important in
pushing for the EGA. The paradox is that despite its prominence in the CMP, the
same underlying factors that provided the compelling reasons to enact such
legislation also fuelled the opposition to the Act within and outside the
government. These arise from the neo-liberal policies that serve the interests
of finance capital and are pursued with equal vigour by the NDA and UPA
governments. An EGA stands in direct conflict with the interests of finance
capital, which is extremely wary of inflation. Any policy measure that increases
expenditure in the economy and moves the terms of trade in favour of agriculture
and rural areas is detrimental to their interests. Thus, their ideologues
prescribe policies that worsen the relative position of the peasantry and
agriculture in the Third World along with a slowdown in overall expenditure.
While advocates fought for a substantive and effective legislation, the
neo-liberals were willing to agree to cosmetic and superficial measures only.
The
main official amendments on the NREG Bill arrived at after intense negotiations
with the Left are a significant step in the right direction. These correctives
remained elusive for a very long time. They include the following: universal
eligibility (all households are entitled to apply for work without BPL
criteria); irreversible guarantee, without "switch off"; time bound
extension to all of rural India in five years; one third of the work to be given
on priority to women applicants; principal role and 50 per cent cost of works to
Panchayati Raj institutions; permissible works to be determined in consultation
with states; more beneficiaries whose private land can be included for
improvement under the scheme; rise in ex gratia from Rs 15,000 to Rs 25,000;
provision of crèche if there are five or more children under the age of six at
a work site. In addition, the minister has agreed in his speech that the Rules
will include timely release of advance funds to states every quarter and
compensation to states for unemployment allowance if funds are not devolved in
time. Additionally, he committed on the floor of the House that the definition
of household will be “nuclear” and the wage will be cost-indexed.
The
NREG Bill that has been adopted is therefore closer to a full-fledged employment
guarantee and a great improvement on what was tabled by the government in
December or approved by the cabinet in August. Though better after the Left’s
interventions, it continues to be problematic on some important aspects. The two
biggest lacunae that remain are the absence of individual entitlements; and the
non-acceptance of the minimum wages set by states. The government was completely
unwilling to give in on these two fronts, and for some time it looked like the
issue would remain unresolved.
In
the original Bill tabled by the government, the section on wages read as
follows: “6. (1) Notwithstanding anything contained in the Minimum Wages Act,
1948, the central government may, by notification, specify the wage rate for the
purposes of this Act: Provided that different rates may be notified for
different areas. (2) Until such time as a wage rate is fixed by the central
government in respect of any area in a state, the minimum wage fixed by the
state government under section 3 of the Minimum Wages Act, 1948 for agricultural
labourers, shall be considered as the wage rate applicable to that area.”
Thus, there was no floor to the wages that could be set by the centre. This
raised the fear that the neo-liberal argument may guide the fixation of very low
wages. The standing committee had recommended statutory minimum wages or Rs 49,
whichever is higher. The centre rejected this, and with a great deal of effort a
floor is now set at Rs 60.
The final amendment arrived at after several rounds of discussions reads
as follows: “6. (1) Notwithstanding anything contained in the Minimum Wages
Act, 1948, the central government may, by notification, specify the wage rate
for the purposes of this Act: Provided that different rates may be specified for
different areas. Provided further that the wage rate specified from time to time
under any such notification shall not be at a rate less than sixty rupees a
day.” Clause 6(2) remains as it is. There is also contradiction between the
minister’s speech and what the clause provides, because he said that minimum
wages set by the states would be paid. If we look at the minimum wages fixed by
the state governments under the SGRY which the ministry of rural development
reported to the standing committee as relevant for the NREG Bill, roughly 70 per
cent of the districts under the Food for Work Programme have wages below Rs 60,
while 5.4 per cent have a wage rate of Rs 60. This notwithstanding, this clause
overrides the Minimum Wages Act which is a compromise that has been accepted for
the moment, which has to be fought against.
BJP’S
CROCODILE TEARS
The
BJP moved very radical amendments, which is ridiculous given their inconsistency
with the policies pursued by their previous NDA government when in power. The
rural distress is clearly an outcome of trade liberalisation, deflation and
specific structural adjustment measures undertaken in the rural sector by their
government. The government rural development expenditure declined as a
percentage of GDP, from 14.5 per cent in the Seventh Plan to 6 per cent in the
Ninth Plan period, implying a projected decline of Rs 50,000 crore in each year
on this count alone. Rural banking by the Scheduled Commercial Banks (SCBs)
worsened in all respects, and the very concept of priority sector lending was
severely diluted. The government of India lowered tariffs and opened up trade
well before requirement under WTO. This was at a time when world prices had
begun to crash due to mounting subsidies given by the advanced capitalist
countries to their agriculture. This exposed Indian farmers to unfair trade,
global price volatility and recessionary international markets. Worse, under the
structural adjustment programmes, the Indian government withdrew subsidies and
extension services. User charges were raised substantially, and the government
reduced subsidies on all agricultural inputs, including seeds, water and
electricity charges, fertilisers, pesticides, and agricultural implements. As a
result, growth of agricultural production fell from 3.5 in the 1980s to 2.0 per
cent per annum in the 1990s, and real income growth fell from 4.5 to 2.5 per
cent per annum over the same period. Employment growth fell from 2.04 per cent
to 0.98 per cent. By 2001, per capita foodgrain availability had fallen to lower
levels than that in the 1950s, and deceleration of growth in foodgrain output
could have been offset by release of buffer stocks through the PDS, increase in
food-for-work programmes, mid-day meal schemes, etc. However, per capita
absorption in the 1990s declined on account of large additions to stocks and
very high and cheap food exports. The existing rural crisis is thus an outcome
of NDA’s neo-liberal policies.
MOBILISATION
The employment guarantee has the potential of turning around the agrarian distress and generating growth. It would mobilise surplus labour and unleash productive forces. Though by no means a complete victory as far as a full-fledged employment guarantee is concerned, it is indisputably a resounding defeat for neo-liberal policies. For this reason, we must remain vigilant and mobilise the rural poor to ensure effective implementation and to prevent global finance from engineering a fiscal crisis to defeat this endeavor.