People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 30 July 24, 2005 |
OFFSHORING, or the outsourcing of services by developed country firms to captive units or independent suppliers in developing countries has for some time now been a source for controversy in the developed countries, especially the US. Arguments that such offshoring involves not just the transfer abroad of new job opportunities that would have arisen in the developed countries, but the loss of existing jobs in the US to offshore locations abound. They derive their strength from reports that specific corporations have been reducing or plan to reduce their workforce in developed-country locations, even while expanding them in developing countries such as India. In the event, calls for protectionist responses that limit and roll-back the offshoring of services have increased dominate the US debate. On the other hand, firms clamouring to retain their tax holidays despite booming profits present outsourcing as the route to India’s economic salvation.
The
recently released Annual Trade Report of the WTO
provides an occasion to revisit these arguments, because a special
chapter in the report focuses on offshoring of IT services and argues that: (i)
the extent of net offshoring is exaggerated; and (ii) that to the extent that
offshoring occurs its negative effects on the source country and positive
benefits for the host country have also both been exaggerated.
The
WTO’s argument begins with pointing to the extremely shaky and predominantly
private sector generated database on the phenomenon. In some cases as in India,
even official information as available in the balance of payments statistics is
collected and collated by a private body --- in this case the National
Association of Software and Services Companies (NASSCOM).
Discrepancies
in the data arise with regard to the size of the global IT services market
itself, besides its outsourced component. For example, the European Information
Technology Observatory (EITO) estimates the size of the global IT services
market, excluding business process (BP) services, at 710 billion dollar (€591
billion) in 2003. On the other hand, the OECD estimates the size of the global
market for outsourced IT and business process services to be close to 260
billion dollar in 2001. Taking into account reasonable estimates of exchange
rate changes and market growth, this makes the EITO estimate much larger than
that of the OECD’s, despite its narrower coverage. Further, Gartner estimates
that out of a total of 663 billion dollar of software and IT services
expenditure in 2003, around 322 billion dollar was outsourced. Though closer to
the OECD’s outsourced services estimate, even this appears higher than the
OECD’s broader estimate.
Similar
discrepancies are seen in estimates of offshoring as well. The OECD places the
value of offshored IT and business service activities at 32 billion dollar in
2003, representing 12.3 per cent of the global IT market. McKinsey, on the other
hand, estimates that US companies offshored IT and business process (BP)
services worth 26 billion dollar to 12 major markets in 2001. The 12 markets
exclude major EU markets and therefore the figure somewhat underestimates the
global offshoring of US companies worldwide Even if we ignore this, since the
share of US companies in global offshoring activities is estimated at 70 per
cent, this suggests that the global value for all offshored IT and BP services
was at 35 billion dollar in 2001, higher than the OECD’s 2003 value.
While
recognising the private nature of the sources of these statistics, the WTO, for
lack of an alternative, places IT and software expenditure worldwide in the
order of 650 to 710 billion dollar in 2003. Total outsourced IT services
(excluding software) are paced at around 285 billion dollar. Offshored IT and BP
services are estimated to have been in the order of 40 to 45 billion dollar in
2003. This places offshored IT and BP services at just 2.5 per cent of world
commercial services exports, valued at 1,800 billion dollar and at a meagre
0.125 per cent of world GDP valued at 36,000 billion dollar. No one can claim
that this is enough to disrupt economic activity and employment in the developed
countries.
The
point is that even of this, the share offshored to captive units is quite
substantial according to available estimates. According to the WTO: “Many
surveys confirm that at present, most offshoring takes the form of captive
offshoring. This view is supported by data on US IT services imports. In 2003,
affiliated trade (or form US subsidiaries or joint ventures abroad) accounted
for 63 per cent of US computer and information services imports, and for 77 per
cent of US imports of other business, professional and technical services, a
proxy for business process services.”
SOFTWARE
EXPORTS
However,
the WTO notes, this conflicts with the NASSCOM view that India’s software
exports of 2003-04 are provided largely by Indian-owned companies. This is the
first of the puzzles offered by the Indian IT industry that needs to be
unravelled. The second is the discrepancy between the volume of IT and
IT-enabled services exports to the US as reflected in the Balance of Payments (BoP)
statistics from India and the US. According to the Reserve Bank of India,
India’s “software” exports amounted to 11.3 billion dollar in 2003. Taking
NASSCOM’s estmates that around 60 per cent of this went to the US market,
software exports to the US in 2003 works out to be 6.77 billion dollar according
to official BoP statistics.
Turning
to the US, official BoP statistics indicate that US imports of IT services
through unaffiliated agents from India amounted to 330 million dollar in 2003.
The same source reveals that the share of unaffiliated trade in total US IT
imports stood at 36.5 per cent. Assuming that the same figure holds for US
bilateral trade with India, the (estimated) imports of IT services from India
works out to just 900 million dollar. US imports of all services (including
affiliated trade) from India, without transport, travel and royalties and
license fees, amounted to 1,139 million dollar in 2003. This represents the
upper limit for total US imports of from India, making the 900 million dollar
figure for IT services appear reasonable.
How
do we reconcile this major difference in the numbers (6.77 billion dollar and
0.9 billion dollar) involved? One of course is to take account of the possible
mis-categorisation of other business services as software services. BoP data on
“business services” are reported under two heads: ‘computer and
information services’ (CIS) and ‘other business services’. However,
national statistics do not reflect a uniform principle with regard to the
allocation of services trade between these two categories. In particular, in
India a range of IT-enabled services, such as call centres and medical
transcription services, are reported along with export of software services. For
example, the Reserve Bank of India’s (RBI) Annual Report 2004 shows that
Indian “software” exports worth 12.2 billion dollar in 2003-04 include
IT-enabled services amounting to 3.6 billion dollar.
But assuming that the figures for India’s exports of “software” to the US is inflated by the same proportion, we should expect that software exports to the US would have amounted to 5.75 billion dollar. This still is way above the US BoP figure. To explain this difference the WTO examines the possibility that what are paid as “salaries” to India IT-workers on short term H-1B visas gets reported as software exports. It is true that the NASSCOM reports that a large share of India’s “software exports” is delivered “onsite”. However, “onsite” delivery by Indians employed abroad can be treated as an export from India only as long as these employees have not been staying abroad for more than one year. If they do they should definitionally be considered residents of the host country. Thereafter, the earnings of these employees are no longer counted in the BOP statistics, although they might reappear later in the form of worker remittances. Unfortunately, information on the number of Indian IT specialists and beneficiaries of H-1B visas who had already worked in the United States for more than one year is not easily available.
So
the WTO supports the view that misallocation of salary payments is possibly what
explains the discrepancy between US and Indian BoP statistics on the basis of
the following argument. Taking the
annual approval of beneficiaries of H-1B visas, the WTO estimates that their
number could have been close to 80,000 in 2003. If this number is multiplied by
the average annual earnings (about 60,000 dollar) of these workers, their total
earnings turns out to be 4.8 billion dollar over the year, which tallies closely
with the discrepancy in the statistics provided by the two countries. So the
exclusion of those who have been there for more than a year could possibly
explain a large part of the discrepancy.
It
is still too early to judge whether the WTO has arrived at a correct conjecture.
But if that conjecture were true it does have implications for the nature of
India’s software success. To start with, it does suggest that onsite delivery
is still an extremely important component of India’s software success.
Further, it speaks for the nature of the software services provided by Indian
firms. The argument is that Indian companies are earning substantial sums based
on a per-hour or per-manday fee charged to firms, which use imported workers to
customise software, solve problems or develop specific applications. Since these
workers are paid a salary in India and an allowance while they are abroad, the
consultancy fee paid by the importing firm is the revenue of the exporting firm
and the difference between the per employee fee and the cost per employee is the
surplus accruing to the exporting firm.
It
has been argued that body-shopping of this kind is representative of activities
that are at the lower end of the software services spectrum. This has
implications for both the quality and sustainability of India’s IT export
boom. India today dominates the global market for outsourced software and
IT-enabled services. NASCCOM quotes an estimate according to which India today
accounts for 44 per cent of the global outsourcing market. This ratio goes up to
55 per cent if only the ITeS-BPO segment is considered. If current growth rates
are to persist either the global market would have to grow at that rate with a
stable Indian share or the industry would have to increase its share of the
global market over time. That is indeed a touch difficult.
SERVICES
IN EXPORT REVENUES
Further, since body-shopping and the ITeS-BPO sector accounts for a rising share of total services export revenues, India’s dependence on the less skill-intensive segments of the software and IT-services sector is overwhelming. This makes it even more difficult to maintain market shares, especially without a substantial drop in revenues per employee, since competitors are more easily generated.
Finally,
even if India’s share of outsourcing revenues remains high, the net benefits
of this are still unclear because of the dominance of a few firms and a
substantial share for captive offshore outsourcing by international firms in the
ITeS-BPO sector. According to NASSCOM figures, in 2003-04 the top 20 software
and IT services exporters accounted for as much as 61 per cent of total export
revenues. And captive ITeS-BPO providers accounted for as much as 65 per cent of
the value of ITeS contracts outsourced to India. This kind of concentration not
only makes the linkage effects of the growth of the industry less significant,
it also has adverse implications for the net foreign exchange earning of the
sector after taking into account repatriation of profits and other payments
abroad.
INEQUALISING
GROWTH
It
must be noted that the absolute employment contribution of the software
and IT services sector makes its position within the Indian economy that of an
enclave. Even at just over a million, the number of workers in software
and IT services amounts to just one quarter of one per cent of all workers in
India as per the 2001 Census, or one-third of one per cent of all main workers
in 2001 or two-thirds of one per cent of all workers outside agriculture and
household industry. This suggests that a sector whose presence in terms of its
contribution to GDP and its contribution to India’s currently comfortable
balance of payments position is indeed signficant, cannot make much of a direct
difference to a substantial section of India’s population. Hence an
excessive dependence on this sector for growth at the margin may be inequalising,
a possibility that the WTO also recognises.