People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 21 May 22, 2005 |
For
the Rural Economy in India
Utsa
Patnaik
Utsa
Patnaik has contributed an
article “Jobs and Food Security in the Era of
Deflationary Economic Reforms”. Since this article deals with three issues, it
has been split into three parts. Each part is being published as an independent
article. The first article is being published in this Issue of PD. The second
and the third in the series will be published in the subsequent issues of PD.
DEFLATIONARY
macroeconomic policies are beloved by international and domestic financial
interest groups who are quite obsessive about controlling inflation and would
prefer to see even an economy with a high rate of unemployment, growing slowly
and raising unemployment further, rather than risk any possibility of prices
rising. International creditors wish to maintain high real interest rates (which
inflation would erode) and are happy with bouts of asset deflation in developing
countries so that these assets can be snapped up at low prices by their
corporations. Their insensate and obsessive fear of inflation can be seen in the
policies advised uniformly by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to 78
developing countries in the 1980s and summarized in Table 1 from an IMF study. The
first three policies – restraint on central government expenditure, limits on
credit expansion, and reduction of budget deficit to GDP ratio, add up together
to a strongly deflationary package and all three were actually implemented at
the same time by four-fifths of the concerned countries, while two-thirds capped
wages and over half devalued their currency.
The
results of deflationary policies of the 1980s in developing have been documented
as sharp decline in rates of investment in both capital formation and in the
social sectors, leading to reduced or negative GDP growth and negative impact on
the human development indicators (see in particular Cornia, Jolly and Stewart
1987, Adjustment with a Human Face).
A number of studies since then have confirmed the adverse impact and have
argued for expansionary policies.
Table
1
Policies
Followed by 78 countries under Fund-guided Reforms
|
Percentage
of Total Number
of Countries Implementing
Policy |
1.
Restraint on central government Expenditure |
91 |
2.
Limits on Credit Expansion
|
99 |
3.
Reduction in Ratio of Budget Deficit to GDP
|
83 |
4.
Wage Restraint
|
65 |
5.
Exchange Rate Policy
|
54 |
Source:
Quoted in Cornia, Jolly and Stewart (eds) Adjustment
with a Human Face 1987, Vol.1,
p.11.
Table
2
Reduction
in Rural Development Expenditures under Economic Reforms, Selected Years
1985–90 to 2000–01 |
|||||
|
1985-90 average |
1993-4 |
1995-6 |
1997-8 |
2000-2001 |
1.
Rural Development Expenditures as Percent of NNP |
3.8
|
2.8 |
2.6 |
2.3 |
1.9 |
2.
Above plus |
11.1
|
8.4 |
6.9 |
6.4 |
5.8 |
Source:
Calculated using current values, from Reserve Bank of India, Report
on Currency and Finance, 1995–6, Statements 8 and 146; and Government of
India, Ministry of Finance, Economic
Survey, various issues 2001–02
to 2003–04. Rural development expenditures here include plan outlays on
agriculture, rural development, special areas programmes, irrigation and flood
control, village and small scale industry. Infrastructure includes power and
transport.
Decelerating Growth Rates of Agricultural Output |
||||
Period |
Foodgrains |
Non-Foodgrains |
All
Crops |
Population |
1980-81
to 1989-90 |
2.85 |
3.77 |
3.19 |
2.1 |
1990-91
to 2000-01 |
1.66 |
1.86 |
1.73 |
1.9 |
Source
: Government of India, Ministry of Finance, Economic
Survey, 2001-02, p.189. Note that slowing down of output growth is much
steeper than slowing down of population growth implying falling per head output.
Table
4
Employment
Decline in Rural India |
|||||
|
Year |
Year |
Year
|
Growth
per Annum |
|
|
1983 |
1993-1994 |
1999-2000 |
1983
to 1993-4 % |
1993-4
to 1999-00 % |
RURAL |
|||||
1.Population, mn. |
546.6 |
658.8
|
727.5 |
1.79 |
1.67 |
2.Labour
force,
mn. |
204.2
|
255.4 |
270.4
|
2.15 |
0.96 |
3.Work
force mn. |
187.9 |
241.0 |
250.9
|
2.40 |
0.67 |
4.Unemployed mn.
(2 –3) |
16.3 |
14.4 |
19.5 |
-
1.19 |
5.26 |
Source:
Government of India, Ministry of Finance, Economic
Survey 2002-03, p.218.
DEFLATIONARY
PACKAGE OF POLICIES
India
has been following exactly the same deflationary package of policies since 1991,
whose impact has been especially severe in India’s agricultural sector which
saw sharp reduction in public planned development expenditures in rural areas,
which has traditionally included agriculture, irrigation – vital for
maintaining output – employment generation programmes, drought- prone areas
and special areas programmes, village and small scale rural industry. Out of
these the employment- generating programmes had assumed a special importance
from the drought year 1987 onwards.
During
the Seventh Plan period marking the pre-reforms phase, from 1985 to 1990, Rs
51,000 crore was spent on rural development (including also village and small
scale industry), amounting to almost 4 per cent of Net National Product, and Rs
91,000 crore or over 7 per cent of NNP was spent on infrastructure. By the mid-
1990s, annual spending on rural development was down to 2.6 per cent of NNP, and
after including infrastructure, less than 7 per cent was being spent compared to
11 per cent during the Seventh Plan. Further declines took place so that by
2000-01 the share of spending under these heads was down to 5.8 per cent of NNP,
the rural development part halving to only 1.9 per cent (see Table 2). I
estimate that in constant 1993-4 prices about Rs 30,000 crore less was being
spent by the end-decade year 1999-2000, compared to the beginning, 1990-91. A
crude point-to-point comparison would suggest an annual income loss of between
120,000 to 150,000 crores of rupees assuming a multiplier value between 4 and 5.
Actual income loss would have been greater taking the cumulative losses over
successive years. This harsh contractionary policy had nothing to do with any
objective resource constraint but simply reflected the loan-conditionalities of
the BWI which were internalized and sought to be justified by the Indian
government.
There
is no economic rationale for believing that “public investment crowds out
private investment” which is the common argument put forward for reducing the
state’s role in rural development. Precisely
the contrary has been shown to hold for certain types of investment essential
for an irrigation-dependent agriculture like India’s such as irrigation
projects of all types. Private tube-well investment is profitable only where the
water table remains high owing to seepage from state-built canal irrigation
systems, and where community integrated watershed management (planting trees and
using check-dams) is encouraged with state help. Private over-exploitation of
ground water has now reached a crisis point in many states in India, with the
water table falling rapidly and with even the richest farmers unable to reach
water after investing heavily in deep bore-wells and submersible pumps.
Other infrastructure investment such as rural power projects, roads, bridges,
school buildings, clinics and so on, are never undertaken by private investors
but are vital for stimulating development and providing livelihoods both
directly to those employed in building them and through the important multiplier
effects of the increased wage incomes being spent on simple consumer goods and
services within the villages. The market for machine made textiles and other
goods also expands.
CUT-BACK OF PUBLIC INVESTMENT & RDE
The
net result of the unwise cut-back of public investment and in RDE has been a
near-halving of both foodgrains and non-foodgrains growth rates in the nineties
compared to the pre-reform eighties, and both have fallen below the population
growth rate (Table 3) leading to falling output per head during the nineties,
continuing at present. The Agricultural Universities had earlier played a major
role in developing and helping to disseminate new crop varieties, and the cut in
funding for research in these Universities by affecting the search for better
rain-fed crop varieties, has also contributed to the deceleration in the growth
of yields. With increasing use of land for commercial and residential purposes,
the gross sown area in India has remained static since 1991, so it is only
through yield rise that output growth can be maintained and it is here that the
failure is evident.
The
combination of decline in state RDE and the near-halving of agricultural growth
has produced a major crisis of rising unemployment. There is fast growing open
unemployment and fall in number of days employed of the work force.
The share of labour force in population, or the participation rate, has declined
reflecting difficulty of finding work, the share of work force to labour force
has declined because open unemployment has been growing at over 5 per cent
annually (Table 4).
The
prospects are dim of unemployed rural workers migrating and finding jobs in
industry: there have also been massive job losses in manufacturing during the
reform period and the share of the secondary sector in GDP has fallen from 29 to
around 22 per cent, indicating de-industrialisation.
The agricultural depression has reduced the share of agriculture in GDP from
about a third at the beginning of the nineties to just over a fifth a decade
later, but the labour force and population dependent on agriculture has hardly
fallen reflecting relative decline in per head incomes. The sector which has
ballooned in an abnormal manner is the tertiary or services sector which now
accounts for over half of GDP.
Only
a small share of services is IT-enabled high income services, business process
outsourcing, domestic tourism services and the like. The major part in
employment terms, is still low-productivity activities in which the rural
displaced workers stagnate at low income levels, servicing the requirements of
the upper income elites who have been improving their real income position fast.
Disposable incomes have risen even faster for this segment since a part of the
neo-liberal reforms include reduction in direct tax rates. Advanced countries
usually have this upper-income 10 to 15 per cent minority of Indians in mind
when they demand market access for their manufactures and agricultural products,
and no doubt 100 to 150 million people is a large potential market. But
the situation of the vast majority of the mainly rural population who not merely
stagnate at low income levels but whose position is considerably worse today
than a decade earlier, cannot be ignored: a potentially highly destabilising
situation is in the making.
While
income and employment reduction through deflationary policies is the first main
reason for loss of purchasing power in rural India, the second main reason is
the unwise opening to global markets through full trade liberalization at a time
from the mid-1990s, when global markets went into recession and primary product
prices started falling – a fall which continues to this day.