People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 21 May 22, 2005 |
Following is the text of the response of the All India People’s Science Network (AIPSN) to the draft National Environment Policy (NEP), 2004 released by the UPA government. Detailing its critique of the policy, AIPSN has demanded that this policy be suitably reformulated with the involvement of people’s movements and organisations.
THE
All India People’s Science Network (AIPSN), a network of state level
peoples’ science movement organisations, after reviewing the current draft NEP
is of the considered view that the existing path of development is unsustainable
and iniquitous in character and has a detrimental impact on the livelihood
security of the rural and urban poor. It is also creating serious environmental
and health risks for the nation as a whole. The AIPSN believes that at the
current juncture, the aim of the Draft NEP should be to reverse these trends and
facilitate transition towards an ecologically and socially just path of
development. Needless to say the policy should also protect the interests of the
nation and the majority of its population in the context of the emerging regimes
of global environmental and economic governance and treaties related to them.
In
this context the formulation of a cross-sectoral National Environment Policy,
2004 would have been a welcome step if it had been preceded by some serious
dialogue and debate amongst different interest groups and mass organisations
over what should have been the nature, scope and jurisdiction of such a policy.
As it happens, the policy has been formulated in a way that can easily mislead
the general public and the interested and affected parties of its real
intentions. Apparently the NEP 2004 derives its legitimacy from the inclusion of
objectives such as to provide for intra and inter-generational equity and
integration of environmental concerns in socio-economic development process and
from the commitment to be guided in the policy and partnership design by the
principles such as internalising the environmental costs into planning process,
precautionary principle, fixing strict liability (even in the absence of
legislation or standards) and preventive action, all of which are
well-intentioned. But the way the NEP identifies the causes of environmental
degradation it does start to show that it lacks intention to make a clean break
with the existing paradigm of development and conservation.
The
NEP has been released within a few months of the formation of a new government
which, in order to actualise the popular mandate, has drawn up a Common Minimum
Programme (CMP) that enunciates priorities and programmes for socio-economic
development with special emphasis on the interests and well-being of disadvantaged
and poorer sections. It is surprising indeed that the NEP is not informed by
these concerns.
It
is significant that the NEP 2004 does not envisage a change in the path of
development to make it anymore ecologically and socially just. Its vision of
structural, institutional and policy interventions is aligned with the type
of changes envisaged that are consistent with the interests of and lifestyle
acceptable to the rich. It fails to acknowledge the special problems facing
the dalits, tribals and other marginalised people in respect of access to
resources, capabilities and markets.
The
NEP 2004 seeks no change in the strategy of economic growth with the aim to
particularly make the patterns of production and consumption ecologically
and socially just for the people who have been victimised by the processes
of economic development, it fails to put sustainable human development on
the national policy agenda in a systematic way. For example the section on
strategies and actions does not call for changes in the industrial and
product structure that would facilitate the introduction of and transition
to sustainable natural resource use. In fact the NEP ignores the issue of
elimination of unsustainable practices of production and consumption of
non-renewable resources by the corporate sector and affluent classes.
It
also pushes the question on the vision and path of sustainable development
under the carpet by placing the entire blame for environmental degradation
on either the poor people or on so called “institutional (read
governmental/ state) and market failures”. All references to “the right
of people and communities” and “inter-generational equity” are only
incidental to these aims and seek to soften their impact and path towards an
ecologically, economically and socially just order.
It
will be pertinent to state here that although the policy document is
claiming that “sustainable development concerns in a sense of human
well-being are a recurring theme in India’s development philosophy”, but
the current document is short of people friendly ideas on its own vision for
sustainable development. This is particularly true of the list of
“incomparable entities” that it enumerates and puts under direct state
control for the purpose of enhancement and conservation of environmental
resources.
The
NEP places undue reliance on economic and fiscal measures to engender
environmental conservation, for example as regards irrigation water
especially groundwater. No one would disagree that proper pricing of natural
resources, taking into account present and future environmental costs, is
desirable. Yet there is little evidence to suggest that pricing alone
ensures resource conservation: it is well known that raising taxation on
petrol/diesel or on automobiles has not brought about any reduction in
automobile purchase, usage or petroleum consumption because, when such
commodities are viewed in some manner as "necessities", rising
costs are merely absorbed or rather passed on elsewhere in the economy. This
overarching economic-fiscal orientation is also evident in the highly
peculiar recommendation that periodic review of the NEP be undertaken by the
Cabinet Committee for Economic Affairs!
Its
key propositions regarding strategies and actions straddle between a
conventional conservationist agenda (excluding people’s rights over the
use of their local resources) and a strategy that seeks to open up the
natural resources sector to market forces. Consequently it also chooses to
transform the role of the Indian State in the direction of facilitating the
market forces to self-regulate their activities for environmental concerns
and confining largely to its own direct interventions to the application of
price and taxation instruments. By doing this the NEP severely dilutes the
development and welfare role and responsibility of the Indian State.
It
consciously chooses to remain silent on what type of institutional forms and
access should be created in order that rights of access and ownership should
be provided to natural resource dependent people. Needless to say, the role
of the state has to be developmental in nature to provide access to
resources to the marginalised sections of the Indian people.
The
NEP attempts to bring issues of the settlement of ownership and control
under the rubric of “institutional failures” or the failure to settle
rights. But it is not successful in doing this because it does not get into
the establishment of a policy framework for what would constitute the
legitimate framework of “rights of use” on different resources. It
states that it will follow the Public Trust Doctrine where the State is
“not an absolute owner, but merely a trustee of all natural resources,
which are by nature meant for public use and enjoyment, subject to
reasonable conditions, necessary to protect the interests of a large number
of people”. While this assertion of the state being not an absolute owner
may have welcome but for the fact that it does not limit the State power
when it comes to the privatisation of natural resources. If the State is not
an absolute owner, can it privatise something it does not own? The extension
of the Protected Areas Network is mandated by this policy. This effectively
means that people will have no rights in this area. But the policy is silent
on the fact on how the State’s power to denotify these areas for
commercial or large developmental projects will also be delimited through
this review of legislation.
By
not specifying how the ownership and right of access shall be established
over these resources the policy is in fact stating that deregularisation is
just another term for privatisation by encouraging environmental investments
which will be made by corporate houses since the resource-dependent poor
people are not in a position to make such investments. For example the
policy makes claims about the rationalisation of Coastal Regularisation Zone
notifications. It specially talks of decentralising “the clearance of
specific projects to State Environmental Authorities, exempting activities
which do not cause significant environmental impacts....”. This
formulation is clearly detrimental to the livelihood of fisherfolk and can
easily lead to the destruction of the coastal ecology. Yet again it fails to
outline the inalienable rights of the fisherfolk, or a mechanisms by which
these rights can be settled. The impression given is that the market forces
will necessitate multi-stakeholder partnerships through which rights will be
settled once again leaving the people to mercy of corporate shipping and
fishing companies.
For
the improvement in access to resources and the grant of right to development
for marginalised people the institutional structures are needed to be
co-evolved in respect of both promotion and regulation. The co-evolved
structures should be in a position to protect the knowledge of local people
and develop that knowledge in a way that the local communities can get the
maximum benefit out of it. This would be possible only if the policy makes
explicit affirmative proposals for the development of ‘marginalised people
friendly’ mechanisms of project evaluation, benefit sharing and the
decentralisation of natural resource management. Such types of proposals are
missing from the document. For example, the document talks of
universalisation of joint forest management (JFM). But
it is quite well known that even in those areas where JFM is already
in practice the forest
dependent people have been gradually marginalised on account of the lack of
co-evolved institutional structures for the promotion and regulation of
markets in non-timber forest produce trade. Clearly the draft policy has no
plans to rectify this problem. This also reflects the fact that there has
been little attempt to learn from past experiences while framing the
document.
At
another place the NEP reiterates the age-old principle of
“non-regularisation” of encroachments in the post-1980 period. In the
same section on forests it also talks of rationalising EIA principles and
solving the problems of delays in clearances. Clearly this is just a
framework for easing controls once imposed by the Forest (Conservation) Act
1980. But the policy does not remove the central weakness in the framework
of this act: it does not provide a redressal system for the complaints of
the people who depend on forests and biodiversity for their livelihood.
The
policy document fails to make a clear commitment towards the making EIA
statements open and public and subject evaluation and contestation by
affected parties. The democratisation of decision making structures and
expertise demands that all stakeholders have the equal opportunity to
evaluate the impact of the project on their livelihood security and
environmental futures. Further all major development and industrial projects
should have the prior informed consent of the affected parties and should
make public their benefit sharing plans and agreements. At another level it
should also be mandatory to provide information to local committees and
bodies, and hold public hearings at periodic intervals.
It
is significant that NEP limits itself largely to creation of market friendly
regulatory regimes to facilitate the introduction of private players in
natural resource management. It does not pay sufficient attention to the
creation of knowledge, expertise, technology, and infrastructure for the
development and diffusion of environment friendly innovations. For example
while outlining the scope of institutional changes needed at the cross-sectoral
level in the section on strategies and actions, it fails to acknowledge the
need to urgently fill the gaps that have emerged in respect of the
development of critical S&T infrastructure required to undertake the
generation of scientific expertise required for environmental monitoring,
enforcement, development and diffusion of technologies needed for the
sustainable development of different socio-economic sectors.
Various
formulations in the NEP Draft appear, intentionally or otherwise, to favour
certain special interest groups and the corporate sector in general.
Commercial "forestry" and industrial-commercial activities along
the long Indian coastline have already been referred to. Mention may also be
made of the fact that fossil-fuel based power generation and automobiles
have been treated with kid-gloves while re-processing of hazardous wastes,
unplanned urban construction etc are simply ignored. More problematically,
NEP talks of the "polluter pays" principle but shelters the
corporate sector with the caveat "with due regard to public interest
and without distorting international trade and investment". The
NEP also argues, without advancing reasons why it is doing so, that
international environmental standards need not be adopted as such in India,
the convenient argument by which asbestos, a whole range of pesticides
including DDT, and many other materials and substances banned in other
countries are allowed to be manufactured and marketed in this country. Such
provisions in the NEP give rise to perhaps needless suspicion that
protection is being offered to certain interest groups who may be adversely
affected by such application of international standards in India as with
automobile emissions, pesticide residues in aerated beverages etc.
The
policy interventions outlined in the document are informed by a narrow
approach to regulatory reforms. It’s propositions are mostly focused on
the problems of transaction costs arising out of the state regulation and
its remedies lie essentially in the government shifting to soft civil law,
fiscal instruments and use of economic principles in decision making. The
policy document is completely oblivious of the obvious fact that
environmental transformation is not an activity performed in isolation but
one which involves a variety of actions within the system, of which the
business groups and communities involved in the process of change forms
part. Business groups and communities not only need instruments that focus
on individual organisations (e.g. financial instruments), but also
instruments that focus on making interventions at the systemic level.
The
NEP totally ignores this systemic aspect of the management of environmental
change; it fails to recognise that the processes of environmental change ask
for (more attention for) system level policy instruments. These instruments
are particularly needed to support
the systemic change management functions relating to the interface
management, building and organising of environmental innovation systems,
providing a platform for learning and experimenting, providing an
infrastructure for strategic intelligence and stimulating demand
articulation, strategy and vision development for the specific processes of
appropriate technological and institutional change. Even a cursory look at
the strategies and actions included in respect of different sectors makes it
clear that the policy document does not envisage the use of such
system-level instruments.
In
the case of India, the instruments of interface management are particularly
important to bring about the convergence and better management of linkages.
Interfaces involving diverse institutions and actors with varying interests
(which may be often conflicting in nature) would need suitable co-ordination
and dispute management to ensure that the disadvantaged sections do not
suffer at the hands of powerful resource consuming actors. The NEP has
little to say how a mechanism for solving dead-locks, conflicts and holding
of broad-based negotiations would be evolved. The market can not fulfil this
function and for larger public interest this is an essential role of the
State.
The
NEP did not mention about the need to provide an infrastructure for
strategic intelligence suited to solving the complex environmental needs and
problems of a variety of sectors and different segments of people. This
means that the State should be responsible for the creation of mechanisms of
technology assessment, foresight, evaluation and benchmarking and
stimulating demand articulation, strategy and vision development for the
specific processes of appropriate technological and institutional change.
The
NEP fails to emphasise on the need for the building and organising of
systems for the development and dissemination of new practices of
sustainable resource use for different sectors. The policy should create a
flexible framework for providing different types of mechanisms for learning
and experimentation by involving interested and affected groups and their
associated people’s organisations (e.g. development of incubation and
bridging organisations for sustainable resource use practices). At present
the NEP assumes that contractual obligations under public private
partnerships, and multi-stakeholder agreements will take care of this
aspect, and puts very little emphasis on the creation of user and bridging
organisations amongst the poor to make use of existing State level R&D
and technology delivery infrastructure.
Given these fundamental weaknesses it is appropriate to conclude that the draft NEP needs to be redrafted. Therefore, the AIPSN demands that this policy be suitably reformulated with the involvement of peoples’ movements and organisations. We would also like the process of public consultation to be given adequate time and publicity. The process of consultation should adopt people-friendly methods and ensure that those people who do not have easy access to internet and English media also have a say and are able to make an informed choice about the type of environmental policy framework that India needs at this juncture.