People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 08 February 20, 2005 |
Bonanza
For The Rich, Misery For The Poor
Sitaram Yechury
The
media reports that the prime minister has spoken during the recent election
campaign to the effect that the impressive performance of the
Indian economy has silenced the critics of liberalisation.
At the outset, everyone who has the interest of India and its people at heart would wish the Indian economy to grow robustly. Further, they would also hope that the benefits of this growth would reach all sections of our people and not be cornered by a few.
The
latter aspect has, obviously, not happened during the course of this decade and
half of economic reforms and liberalisation. The fate of the “India Shining”
and “feel good” campaigns at the hustings recently, resoundingly underlines
this fact. The simple truth of the matter is that the gains of such a process of
liberalisation have been confined mainly to a small section of our population,
while for a majority, the living conditions have deteriorated, at best
stagnated. The agrarian distress that continues to sweep across the country is
testimony to this fact.
Having
said this, let us now examine the experience of our economy during these years
of liberalisation. There are three disquieting factors that need to be taken
note of. (All statistics in this article have been taken from the
official website of the finance ministry: Public Finance Statistics.)
First,
during the course of these years,
the gross central taxes to GDP ratio has declined from 10.62 in 1989-90 to 8.26
in 1998-99, increasing marginally to 9.5 in 2000-01 (the last year for which
revised estimates are available). Before
we come to the decline in this ratio, it must be noted that the levels of this
ratio in India are one of the lowest in the world — even
the “Asian Tigers” have a tax GDP ratio which is over 20! Advanced
countries of Europe have a ratio over 30 and close to 40, while Scandinavian
countries like Sweden have a ratio which is above 50.
Given
this, the objective in India ought to have been to
increase this ratio, so that the government would have greater revenues
at its disposal to fulfill the constitutionally mandated social obligations to
the people. Instead, what we have
is an actual decline in this ratio which means the government’s revenues,
instead of growing, are actually contracting.
A decline in tax
GDP ratio means that those who pay the taxes are now paying less than before. This is evident in the series of tax concessions given to the
rich and to the corporate sector over these
years of liberalisation. These were done in the name of providing incentive for
investment and, therefore, for economic growth.
Such
concessions are, actually, subsidies that are provided for the rich.
There are two types of subsidies: one,
where the government spends in order to provide
relief for the poor by subsidising items of mass consumption; the other, where
the government does not collect from the rich what it used to collect in the
past, thus, providing them relief to the corresponding amount.
The former are categorised as subsidies by the liberalisation pundits
and considered as burden on the exchequer. The latter are called
incentives, thus, giving a veneer of respectability
for subsidising the rich.
Now,
one per cent point of our GDP is close to Rs 30,000 crores.
A drop of 2 per cent points in the tax GDP ratio means a loss in
government revenues to the tune of nearly Rs 60,000 crores annually.
If this amount had not been foregone, then the government of the day
would always have substantial resources to undertake expenditures aimed at
improving the well-being of the vast mass of the Indian people.
Thus, the years of liberalisation have seen a process where the rich gets
subsidised at the expense of the poor.
Far
from silencing its critics, these years of liberalisation had brought into
currency the famous “anti-incumbency” factor in Indian politics.
If, indeed, the critics of liberalisation were silenced, then
neither Chandrababu Naidu nor S M Krishna would have lost the elections.
Or, for that matter, since the initiation of the liberalisation policies, no
incumbent prime minister in India, from Narasimha Rao downwards, has ever been
re-elected. Thus, the shrinking
revenue base of the government will have to be reversed if the people’s
discontent has to be met. Any such
reversal, which must be done under popular pressure, amounts to the vindication
of the critics of liberalisation, such as us.
Secondly,
the entire claim of liberalisers has been on strengthening the industrial sector
in our country particularly domestic manufacture. Any hope of India emerging as a post-industrial society is
contingent upon India first becoming an industrial society. India, by any
measure, is not yet a fullfledged industrial society. The thrust of
liberalisation was, thus, to strengthen domestic manufacturing, in order to
transform India into a modern industrial society. What has been the record on this score? The share of manufacturing to GDP (factor cost) which stood
at 18.7 in 1990-91 declined to 15.6 in 2003-04.
Now, if the share of manufacturing has, actually, been declining instead
of growing, then there is something seriously at fault.
What is required is an earnest introspection
and not rhetorical thunder. The reason for this (decline in the share of
manufacture GDP ratio) is not far to seek.
Any economist worth his salt will tell us that the crucial factor which determines the growth of the manufacturing sector is the domestic demand at any point of time in the economy. If the domestic demand is not growing at a sufficient pace to sustain industrialisation, then serious bottlenecks appear for the growth of domestic manufacturing sector.
This
is precisely what is happening in India. The
emphasis so far, during the years of reform, has been the pre-occupation to
provide easy access to capital. This is both in terms of its cost (interest
rates) and its availability. But the mere availability and accessibility of
capital does not automatically transform into increase in production. For, the
simple truth is that unless what is produced is consumed, production cannot
increase. If the overall
purchasing power in the society remains stagnant, if not declining, then the
domestic demand fails to grow. Thus, despite easy access and availability of
capital, production does not increase due to the contraction of
domestic demand, and, hence, domestic market.
The
critics of liberalisation, like us, have been repeatedly pointing out that
unless domestic demand is expanded rapidly, the strengthening of domestic
manufacturing and India’s industrial society, thus, cannot take place. This,
in turn, requires a massive dosage of public investment which, while building
the required social and economic infrastructure, provides jobs to people
which, in turn, gets translated into greater domestic demand for goods
which, in turn, provides the impetus for a growth in domestic manufacturing.
Instead
of adopting such a course, the process of liberalisation continues to focus on
what the economists call the “capital constraint”.
In reality, however, the real bottleneck in Indian economy is the
“demand constraint”. Unless
this is addressed in earnest, the potential of the Indian economy to develop
with a robust health will not take place.
Thirdly,
the real health of any economy can be gauged from the levels of domestic capital
formation that takes place. This is
so for the simple fact that capital formation sustains both the fundamentals of
the economy and its future potential for growth.
During the course of these reforms, the ratio of capital formation to
GDP, at factor cost, which stood at 26.3 in 1991 declined to 22.6 in 2001-02.
While provisional figures for 2003-04 indicate that it is inching towards the levels where
it stood in 1990-91. In other words, all through these years of
liberalisation, even at the merciful best, we can only conclude that the gross
capital formation in the Indian economy has stagnated. But the continuous
decline during the course of one whole decade has, actually, weakened the
economic fundamentals. If the
recent upturn is a reflection of a rethink on this score, then it is welcome.
But only time will tell if this is a sustainable trend.
These
three parameters put together throw up serious challenges before the Indian
economy and consequent welfare of its people. What is required is consistent
sustainable growth accompanied by a significantly higher index of distributive
justice. As long as the agrarian
distress continues to haunt vast tracts of our country characterised by
starvation deaths and distress suicides, the critics of liberalisation will
continue to point out the gross inadequacies of the economic policies in
redressing people’s misery.
In
the final analysis, it must be, once again, underlined that one feature of the
2004 people’s mandate was the overwhelming assertion by the Indian people that
the focus of the economic policies must be people’s welfare and not only
the growth of corporate profit. It
is such a shift that the people expect from the UPA government. It is such a
shift that the Common Minimum Programme seeks to embark upon. Concentration on
implementing these aspects of the Common Minimum Programme would serve this
government better.