People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 08 February 20, 2005 |
The Chinese Growth Miracle
CHINA is widely regarded as one of the “success stories” of globalisation, emerging into a giant economy of the 21st century. The successes that have been identified are in terms of high and sustained rates of growth of aggregate and per capita national income; the absence of major financial crises that have characterised a number of other emerging markets; substantial reduction in income poverty. These results in turn are viewed as the consequences of a combination of “prudent” yet extensive programme of global economic integration and domestic deregulation, as well as sound macroeconomic management.
This
experience is then used to argue the case for globalisation and to indicate the
potential benefits that other developing countries can reap, as long as they
also follow “sensible” macroeconomic policies. But there are very specific
features of the Chinese experience which have allowed such rates of growth to be
sustained, that are rarely mentioned in the discussion. This is why Chinese
economic growth warrants a closer look.
China
recorded an annual trend rate of growth of real GDP of 9.8 per cent during the
quarter century ending in 2003. This truly remarkable pace of growth for a
period of over two decades has been punctuated with concern about bouts of
deflation or overheating. Macroeconomic management in
China appears to have more to do with dealing with these cycles around a
relatively high trend rate of growth, rather than with realising and/or
sustaining that trend itself.
China’s
exceptional growth performance over the past three decades is most fundamentally
a reflection of the high investment rates that have characterised the economy
over this period. Capital formation as a share of GDP has been very high by
international standards over the past thirty years, varying between 32 per cent
and 44 per cent of GDP. There has also been substantial volatility in this
indicator, around an increasing trend. As
shown in Chart 1 and Table 1, rates of growth of GDP have been strongly
associated with investment rates,
which is only to be expected.
The cyclical pattern of aggregate income growth around a high trend rate
therefore appears to a result of the pattern of investment growth over this
period.
Year |
Investment
rate |
Rate
of growth of GDP |
Year |
Investment
rate |
Rate
of growth of GDP |
1979 |
36.2 |
7.6 |
1992 |
37.3 |
14.2 |
1980 |
34.9 |
7.8 |
1993 |
43.5 |
13.5 |
1981 |
32.3 |
5.3 |
1994 |
41.3 |
12.7 |
1982 |
32.1 |
9.0 |
1995 |
40.8 |
10.5 |
1983 |
33.0 |
10.9 |
1996 |
39.3 |
9.6 |
1984 |
34.5 |
15.2 |
1997 |
38.0 |
8.8 |
1985 |
38.5 |
13.5 |
1998 |
37.4 |
7.8 |
1986 |
38.0 |
8.9 |
1999 |
37.1 |
7.1 |
1987 |
36.7 |
11.6 |
2000 |
36.4 |
8.0 |
1988 |
37.4 |
11.3 |
2001 |
38.0 |
7.5 |
1989 |
37.0 |
4.1 |
2002 |
39.2 |
8.3 |
1990 |
35.2 |
3.8 |
2003 |
42.3 |
9.3 |
1991 |
35.3 |
9.2 |
|
|
|
The
question then becomes, what explains this pattern of volatile but generally high
rates of investment? It is evident that the stop-go cycles that characterise
investment reflect the broader macroeconomic policy of adjusting domestic
investment (and indeed consumption demand) to price changes. Macroeconomic
policy generally – and therefore aggregate investment, which continued to be
substantially influenced by government decisions given the nature of the economy
- appears to have been strongly responsive to the inflation rate. Higher
investment rates have caused high inflation in the subsequent period, thereby
leading to cutbacks in investment.
Despite
the volatility, the investment rate of the economy increased from 34.5 per cent
of GDP for the three year period at the start of the “economic reforms”
(1979-81) to 39.8 per cent for the three year period 2001-03. Most recent data
indicate that the investment rate in China is around 45 per cent currently.
HIGH
RATES OF
SAVINGS
These
imply rates of domestic saving which are exceptional not only by international
standards, but more particularly for an economy at China’s level of per capita
GDP. Such high rates of domestic saving in turn imply a suppression of domestic
consumption which is only possible with high and/or growing income inequality,
which allows a substantial proportion of incremental income to be saved. If this
argument is accepted, then growing
inequality is not simply an adverse fallout of the pattern of growth in China
thus far, but an important factor behind such growth, enabling the sustained
increase in investment rates which is the most obvious engine of economic
expansion.
It
may be argued that domestic savings has been less significant than foreign
savings, and in particular FDI, in allowing for such high rates of investment.
This is particularly so because of the emergence of China as the second largest
recipient (and the largest in the developing world) of FDI, which has increased
from near zero in the early 1980s, to more than $50 billion in recent years on
average. However, in fact China’s
dependence upon external capital for financing investment has been relatively
low, especially when compared to other developing countries. The ratio of
foreign capital inflow to GDP rose to reach 8 per cent in 1994, and thereafter
has hovered around 5 per cent.
Furthermore, the large inflows of the past two years have not contributed to
domestic investment, macro-economically speaking, since they have been
associated with even higher domestic savings rates and the consequent build-up
of foreign exchange reserves.
GROWING
INEQUALITY AND THE HIGH
RATE OF GROWTH
Therefore,
the role of high investment
– itself related to the overall development and macroeconomic stance of the
government, which extends well beyond purely budgetary expenditures to its
control over off-budget investments etc., has been critical in achieving the
extraordinary growth of the past decades.
And this has been permitted by the pattern of growth which has allowed
incremental incomes to be concentrated in certain regions and among certain
groups, thus enabling high savings rates to be continue and even increase over
time. There is evidence of high and growing inequality in China in recent years,
which has had mainly spatial dimensions, in terms of growing income and
consumption inequality between rural and urban areas as well as across regions
(between the more rapidly growing Eastern region, and the central and western
regions).
But
the implicit dependence upon increasing inequality is not the only reason why
other developing countries should be careful when trying to emulate the Chinese
performance. There is a basic difference in economic structure between the
Chinese economy and other capitalist developing economies.
Even throughout the period being considered, the basic elements of a command
economy have been much in evidence in China. Even after the quite sweeping
economic reforms that have taken place since 1979, state control over
macroeconomic balances remains substantial.
Furthermore,
because of the significance of state-owned enterprises and TVEs in total
production, the ability to influence aggregate demand does not depend only upon
fiscal policy in terms of purely budgetary measures, since many “off-budget”
expenditures can be increased or reduced. Further, monetary policy as is
generally understood in capitalist economies has very little meaning in China
where private financial activity is limited and state-owned banks still dominate
overwhelmingly in the provision of credit. This means that for most of the
period under discussion, macroeconomic policies in China were necessarily very
different and had very dissimilar implications, from those in capitalist
developing economies. It also makes the Chinese experience one which is only
easily replicated by other countries.