People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXIX
No. 01 January 02, 2005 |
Back
To Bashing Subsidies
Jayati
Ghosh
THE
Common Minimum Programme (CMP) of the UPA government promised many things. On
some of the more crucial issues (such as on the Employment Guarantee ACT) the
current central government has shown itself to be less than enthusiastic in
terms of fulfilling the true spirit of its promise. But on other matters which
are more in tune with the basic neo-liberal economic policy paradigm which the
government continues to uphold, it has acted with alacrity.
CUTBACKS
IN
SUBSIDIES
The
most recent example is in terms of the debate on subsidies provided by the
central government. The CMP had promised that “All subsidies will be
targeted sharply at the poor and the truly needy like small and marginal
farmers, farm labour and urban poor.” However,
the actual analysis provided by the finance ministry in its recent Report
prepared with assistance from the National Institute of Public Finance and
Policy (Central
government subsidies in India: A report,
December 2004) suggests that this is to be used as a justification for overall
cutbacks in subsidies, regardless of their effects on the poor and needy.
This
discussion is not new, of course: the period since 1991 has been characterised
by a generalised distaste for subsidies among policy makers, who have tended to
blame them for virtually all fiscal problems, and have used this smokescreen to
divert attention from the inability to raise tax revenues. And so declarations
by the government as well as explicit attempts to reduce direct subsidies on
food and fertiliser have been important parts of the ‘economic reform’
programme since 1991.
All
this has been despite the fact that direct subsidies paid by the central
government amounted to a very small proportion of GDP over this entire period.
Chart 1 shows that since 1991, central government subsidies have never crossed 2
per cent of GDP. Indeed, the ratio of all direct subsidies paid by the central
government to GDP has actually fallen from around 1.85 per cent in the triennium
beginning 1990-91 to 1.6 per cent in the triennium ending 2003-04.
This
is really a trivial amount not only in terms of the past, but also in relation
to international experience. In
countries of western Europe, for example, direct subsidies in the form of
unemployment benefits and social security can make up as much as half of the
current spending of governments.
IMPLICIT SUBSIDIES
Because
direct subsidies are so low, the obsession with reducing them has also
necessarily required that the attention be shifted from direct to “indirect”
or implicit subsidies, calculated on the basis of working out the excess of
expenditure over receipts for all major items of government expenditure. As
early as 1997, a similar Discussion Paper released by the then government (which
contained many of the faces that are so prominent today) concluded that total
subsidies (including these implicit subsidies reflecting low or non-existing
user charges for public services) in India were not only four to five times
higher than explicit subsidies, but constituted an unacceptable 14.4 per cent of
GDP.
This
estimate was arrived at from budget documents simply by calculating the
shortfall in public revenues (or “recovery” of expenditure through charges)
relative to the actual public expenditure incurred. Using the notion of
“merit” and “non-merit” subsidies,
it argued that subsidies accounting for 10.7 per cent of GDP were
unwarranted.
As
a result, the 1997 paper argued that there was a strong case for an almost
across-the-board increase in user charges for services provided by the central
and state governments. This was then used to justify the increase in fertiliser
prices which had negative effects not only on fertiliser consumption and farm
productivity, but also on the viability of cultivation. It was used to explain
the completely ham-handed and ultimately counterproductive attempt to reduce the
food subsidy by raising issue prices of food grain and “targeting” the poor.
This
led to reduced offtake and not only a paradox of large publicly held food stocks
in midst of hunger, but also an actual increase in subsidies on holding of
stocks, which were then exported at prices even lower than earlier denied to the
domestic poor.
INVALID
Several
critiques of that paper comprehensively established that the basic methodology
of this exercise was invalid. The classification of merit and non-merit
subsidies emerged as being very subjective and often bizarre. The principal
failure of this methodology was that it recognised only one reason (the presence
of externalities) why the private valuation of benefits could deviate from their
social value to society. But subsidies are essentially no more than negative
taxes, so externalities cannot be the only reason why societies choose to
subsidise particular activities, just as there are basic socio-political and
income-distributional decisions which determine the pattern of taxation. In
fact, there can be many cases where the fact that public expenditure exceeds
cost recovery need not be a problem but could in fact be socially desirable.
This
is why the developed industrial nations have created an elaborate welfare state,
which has been dismantled only partially even in the current
“market-friendly” ideological environment, and why direct subsidies continue
to be such an important part of the expenditure of such governments.
Given
this background, it is disturbing to see the current finance ministry producing
almost the same false arguments of the earlier Paper, and coming to even more
unwarranted conclusions with respect to policy. The only modification (which is
not really of much signfiicance) is the further segregation of “merit”
subsidies into two categories based on degree of merit. The methodology for
calculating implicit subsidies is the same, and yields a figure of 4.18 per cent
of GDP for the year 2003-04.
Even
the calculations presented in the Paper indicate that these are mostly spent on
critical areas such as agriculture, industry and education. And these individual
implicit subsidies come to tiny percentages of GDP, so small that they are
barely to be noticed in public finance terms. Chart 2 provides an estimate of
these. In fact, if social services such as
health and education as well as expendtiure for the development of agriculture
and industry is to be provided in a socially optimal way and provided to all of
those who are poor and/or deserving, then higher
levels of implict subsidy are called for, not lower ones.
QUESTIONABLE RECOMMENDATIONS
But
this faulty calculation is then used to make very sweeping and even alarming
recommendations for cutting all subsidies. Based on the unjustified axiom that
even so-called “merit” subsidies should be reduced as much as possible, the
Report makes policy proposals that are not only wrong-headed but also
breathtaking in their insensitivity to the current economic situation and
problems of ordinary people.
Thus,
it calls for reducing Minimum Support Prices for farmers at a time of widespread
agrarian crisis. It suggests that the present two-tier system of prices in the
Public Distribution System should be done away with (presumably by revising the
lower prices upwards) along with a system of food coupons for BPL families.
Fertiliser prices should be raised. LPG and kerosene subsidies, which affect
largely middle class and poor households, are seen as objectionable and
requiring further reduction, notwithstanding the recent price hikes which have
already adversely affected the poor.
Economic
services are to be priced to varying degrees, which essentially means increasing
user charges regardless of the merits and positive externalities of the services
in question. Even social services do not escape the net: the Report argues that
“while human development is a necessary concern of the welfare state. It may
be necessary to reassess policies in this area at the micro level to temper this
concern with the equally legitimate concern of burgeoning public
expenditures.” (page 22)
NEO-LIBERAL
FISCAL
STRATEGY
The
irony is that in fact public expenditures have not been burgeoning – as a share of GDP, non-interest public
expendiutre has actually been falling in recent years, and this is part of the
economic problem of the country. This falling share of public expenditure has
been associated with much less infrastructure development, poor and declining
public services, and a collapse of employment generation. So the
economic agenda should really be to think of ways of increasing public
expenditure, not cutting it further.
The
focus on reducing expenditure only comes about because of the failure to raise
tax revenues.
And this has been an integral part of the fiscal strategy associated with
neo-liberal reform. The cuts in indirect and direct tax rates have been
associated with falling central tax to GDP ratios, but the current finance
ministry does not appear to see reversing this trend as a priority. Instead, it
has already simply given away around Rs 6,000 crore to stockbrokers as lost
taxes, first by replacing the capital gains tax with a turnover tax, and then by
reducing that proposed tax to a fraction of the original demand because of
protests on Dalal Street.
All
fiscal measures have very strong implications for income distribution. And they
reflect very clearly the intentions of the government and which sections of the
people and the economy the government serves. If this Paper is an accurate
reflection of the curent thinking of the government in the matter of subsidies,
then it is bad news not only for the poor and needy who require such subsidies
for survival, but also for development of the economy in general.