People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVIII
No. 24 June 13, 2004 |
The
Verdict And The Way Ahead
C P Chandrasekhar
Verdict 2004 was a vote against neo-liberal economic reforms. To respect this verdict the new government should formulate a socially beneficial growth strategy.
THERE
are many meanings that could be read into the defeat of the Bharatiya Janata
Party-led National Democratic Alliance (NDA). It was, in the first instance, a
rejection of the pursuit, through state-mediated and independent channels, of a
divisive social and communal agenda. But, one must remember, the BJP had sensed
the danger of using, for electoral purposes, the blatantly communal platform
that had in the past helped it rise rather rapidly from near obscurity to
national prominence. It had, therefore, made its self-perceived success in
governing the economy the focus of its election propaganda hyped by its media
ma. However, in reality, notwithstanding the buoyant stock market, the large
foreign reserves, the Information Technology-enabled boom and the rebound from
drought year 2002-03, economic performance during the NDA rule was poor. An
agrarian crisis, decelerating employment growth, higher morbidity and mortality
in the small business economy and the wearing down of a social sector starved of
funds had all meant that much of India was waning not shining. Not surprisingly,
as revealed by a post-poll survey of the Centre for the Study of Developing
Societies and Lokniti (The Hindu, May 20, 2004), economic performance
during NDA rule was perceived as poor, with some variation depending on the
class position of the respondents. While just 20 per cent of the poor felt that
there was any improvement in their economic condition under the previous
government, even among the upper middle class only 41 per cent perceived an
improvement.
In
addition, there are signs that there is some resentment over the unequal
distribution of the benefits of whatever growth did occur. The perception that
government should reduce inequalities in land ownership through ceilings on land
holdings and intervene to redress income inequalities that seemed to predominate
among those surveyed. Verdict
2004, therefore, can also be seen as an expression of anger at the adoption of a
strategy and of success indicators that meant little for most Indians,
especially the poorer among them.
REJECTION
OF NEO-LIBERAL
POLICIES
Significantly,
the dissatisfaction with their economic condition, which was “high” among
about a third of the poor, seems to have translated itself into a rejection of
the economic policies that constitute the neo-liberal reform programme embraced
by the NDA. Disinvestment found favour with just 20 per cent of those polled and
downsizing of government found just 29 per cent in favour. Responses such as
these do suggest that the lack of improvement in or even worsening of their
economic condition was seen by those affected as being related in some sense to
the acceleration of the “reform” programme by the NDA government. That is, from
the economic point of view, Verdict 2004 was a vote against neo-liberal economic
reform as well.
It
is not surprising, therefore, that commentators of widely varying persuasions
sense in the verdict a disillusionment with reform, even, if not always, a
complete rejection. What is surprising, however, is the response of much of the
media and large sections of the urban elite to this feature of the verdict. The
concern is not with the ways in which the reform can be stalled, modified and
even reversed where necessary in order to respect the popular mandate. Rather,
the sections of the media and market analysts seem to be gripped by the fear
that the new government would actually respect the verdict and resort to such
measures. Every indication of caution or a rethink on reform is treated as a
recipe for disaster. And every statement from ministers in the new Cabinet is
searched through for signs of reassurance that the reforms would continue.
This
campaign for “continuity” is backed of course with a suitable reading of
movements of the Sensex. Any decline is presented as evidence that an
irresponsible statement or act has frightened the markets; any rise is seen as
evidence that normalcy is being restored and continuity assured. The message is
clear: the role of the government is to calm the market. And the index of a calm
market is asymmetric: the Sensex cannot decline, but it can rise without fear.
It
should be obvious that when the new government formulates and then fleshes out
its economic programme it must dismiss this market-linked rhetoric that
reforms must continue whatever the verdict. But it cannot ignore these
manoeuvres. It is not just that the media and the markets can be used to create
panic of a kind that browbeats the government into holding back on what the
mandate requires it to do. Inasmuch as the principal movers in today’s markets
are foreign institutional investors and the notorious hedge funds, their exit on
being dissatisfied with any effort by the government to respect the popular
mandate, will involve the outflow of foreign exchange that can impact on the
currency market and lead to a run on the rupee. Even if the Reserve Bank of
India today has large foreign currency reserves that it can put to use to defend
the rupee, every such action can be read as a signal that the rupee is
weakening, accelerating the outflow and threatening a currency crisis.
If
such a crisis ensues, the experience of a large number of similarly placed
developing countries indicates, the room for manoeuvre for the new government
will be severely restricted. It would be confronted with deflation but would be
under pressure not to reflate the economy by increasing its expenditure. To
prevent itself from being straitjacketed by those financial profiteers who have
thrived on the outcomes of “economic reform” under the BJP and by sections
of the media which too have benefited from the easy liquidity conditions and the
credit-financed boom in urban enclaves that capital inflows had generated, some
action to curb volatile capital flows, both in and out of the stock market, is
necessary. Thus, the first step on the way ahead must be a minimal set of
measures of capital control that helps the government retain and even expand its
room for manoeuvre. This is not blasphemy: it is what all developed countries
did when they were at and beyond a stage of development similar to India’s,
and this is what some other developing countries, such as Chile and Malaysia,
did at different points in time with positive effect.
RESTORING THE ROLE OF THE STATE
Once
such room for manoeuvre has been garnered, there are two issues that the new
government must squarely confront: First, if markets fail from the point of view
of the vast majority, as they clearly have, they must be reined in. So the areas
in which the state must restore and even expand its role need to be identified
and the segments in which markets must be regulated and controlled and agents
must be disciplined singled out. Second, if the state is to restore and expand
its role in these and other areas, it needs the wherewithal to finance that
role. This requirement is the greater because of evidence that the deceleration
and even decline of public investment in areas such as agriculture,
infrastructure and the social sectors, were crucial in delivering the outcomes
that were rejected by Verdict 2004. The new government must, therefore, find
ways of raising the rate of investment, despite the fact that under pressure
from international finance and the international financial institutions,
previous governments have internalised the logic that aggregate expenditure must
be curtailed in order to keep the fiscal deficit under control. With
revenue expenditures proving sticky and “reform” eroding the tax base, this
has necessitated a cut in much-needed capital and social sector expenditures.
SLOWDOWN
IN THE RATE
The
most damaging failure of the growth process since the early 1990s has been its
inability to deliver adequate employment opportunities.
Results from the quinquennial surveys of the National Sample Survey Organisation
reveal a sharp, and even startling, decrease in the rate of employment
generation across both rural and urban areas. Indeed, so dramatic is the
slowdown in the rate of employment growth that it calls into serious question
the pattern of growth over the last decade.
Growth
rates of employment Annual
compound rates per cent |
||
|
Rural |
Urban |
1983
to 1987-88 |
1.36 |
2.77 |
1987-88
to 1993-94 |
2.03 |
3.39 |
1993-94
to 1999-00 |
0.67 |
1.34 |
At
the level of the central government this took the form of the now-ridiculed
“India Shining” campaign. This deceleration in employment growth occurred
despite the immense opportunity for expanding employment that arose in the late
1990s because of the accumulation of huge food stocks with the government. Using
these stocks and combining it with some rupee expenditure, the government could
have launched a massive food-for-work programme geared to improving and creating
rural infrastructure of various kinds. Inasmuch as inadequate investment in such
infrastructure was principally responsible for the slow growth of agricultural
gross domestic product (GDP), such a programme would have helped stimulate
agricultural growth as well and ensured second-order employment generation
effects. The launch of such a programme, parallel to existing employment
generation programmes that must be strengthened, must be a high priority for the
government.
ACCELERATING
Overall,
greater dynamism in agriculture and its concomitant effects on non-agricultural
employment in rural areas are crucial for accelerating employment growth. This
in turn requires reversing the decline in capital formation in agriculture.
Given the evidence that private investment follows public investment in the
agricultural sector, public capital formation needs to be stepped up
substantially.
The
other important means for increasing employment is a revival of the small
business economy, damaged by the withdrawal of measures of protection, including
protection from import competition. For example, reserving areas of production
for the small-scale sector makes little sense if simultaneously imports of those
products are not merely liberalised but duties on them reduced substantially. In
addition, a major reason for the closure of small-scale units is inadequate
access to credit of the right magnitude at the right time. Even prior to the
reforms of the 1990s, small industry had complained about the lack of access to
credit. Since financial liberalisation has diluted programmes aimed at directing
credit to the priority sectors, undermined development banking institutions, and
rendered the banks less willing to lend to small customers with limited
collateral by making profitability the sole indicator of banking performance,
this problem has increased substantially. Thus a rethink of the nature and
direction of financial sector reform is called for when considering options for
accelerating employment generation.
It
is not just import liberalisation and deficient rural credit that affects
employment. It is indeed true that foreign direct investment (FDI) is not as
inimical to the economy as speculative financial capital. But FDI often
displaces domestic production by acquiring local firms rather than creating
greenfield projects, as has happened in several sectors such as the soft drinks
industry. Since the import intensity of foreign firms is high, this amounts to a
form of implicit de-industrialisation. So foreign investment should be
encouraged only in areas where it expands domestic production, either by using
India as a base to supply hitherto inaccessible export markets or by
substituting for imports in essential high-technology areas. This would also
ensure that foreign exchange needed to meet outflows from these firms is
simultaneously earned or saved. That is, FDI should be encouraged in areas where
it expands domestic economic activity without adverse balance of payments
implications.
REASSESSING
Financial
reform must be reassessed also because of the second area of concern that the
new government must tackle immediately: rural indebtedness. Reports of suicides
by farmers routinely point to an unbearable debt burden as being the cause of
their extreme action. While a range of factors such as the failure of high-cost
cash crops into which farmers have diversified or an unexpected fall in prices
of those crops account for the inability to repay debt, an important factor is
the high interest rates paid on debt taken from informal sources. The evidence
suggests that the dependence of rural producers on such debt has increased
during the 1990s. With financial reform resulting in reduced access to debt from
the formal sector and banks even closing down rural branches as part of a
process of restructuring, this dependence has increased substantially. The
shift to “universal banking” at the expense of development banking and
directed credit programmes has far-reaching implications, necessitating a halt
to, and even some reversal of, such policies.
In
the long run, improving the lot of the agriculturists requires ensuring a
reasonable return for them. This requires reining in their costs and
guaranteeing them appropriate prices. On the cost front, the government must
ensure that the prices of crucial inputs such as power and fertilizer are not
allowed to escalate on the grounds that prices charged by those providing those
inputs must include a healthy return over and above actual and not even
normative prices. This requires the acceptance of two principles. The first is
that the prices charged by public sector units should not be assessed in
isolation but treated as one among the many instruments that constitute the
government’s tax-cum-subsidy regime. In the past, on the one hand, public
sector prices have been raised to increase budgetary revenues or reduce
budgetary expenditures and, on the other, large tax concessions have been handed
out to those in the higher tax slabs, which has contributed to a decline in the
tax-GDP ratio. This implicitly treats public sector prices as one element in a
redistributive fiscal regime, even though this reality is shrouded in the
rhetoric of efficiency. While continuing to use public sector prices as
redistributive instruments, it is necessary to ensure that such redistribution
favours the poor.
The
second is that prices received by farmers must not be allowed to fall relative
to costs as a result of the liberalisation of imports, reduction of import
duties and the gradual dismantling of the minimum support price scheme. This has
indeed been one consequence of the reform, which needs to be corrected.
UNIVERSAL
PUBLIC
While
these are policies directly aimed at alleviating some of the most adverse
consequences of reform for the poor, corrective reform is required in other
areas as well. One is the strengthening of the public distribution system (PDS).
Experience under the NDA has made clear that efforts at targeting subsidies
at the poor neither achieve their goal nor result in a reduction in the subsidy
bill. Hence, as the high-powered committee set up by the NDA government itself
had recommended, there is need for a universal PDS that makes no distinction
between populations above and below the poverty line. The tendency to raise
the prices of food issued through the PDS must be abjured since the expectation
that this would reduce subsidies has been proved completely wrong. It only
reduces off take from the PDS resulting in an accumulation of stocks with the
government. The consequent increase in the carrying costs of the Food
Corporation of India (FCI) results in a large subsidy bill, which does not reach
the poor. Moreover, embarrassed by the large stocks, the previous government
callously chose to sell it to traders for export purposes at below poverty line
(BPL) prices, ensuring that the subsidy ended up as trader’s profits or
benefited international consumers.
Another
area that must be urgently tackled is the decline in social sector expenditures
and the consequent shortfall in social sector provision. To make such
expenditures effective, they must be linked to a set of specific objectives,
among which must figure the provision of free and universal primary education of
quality, and free and universal primary health care of quality, within a fairly
short time horizon.
If
employment programmes are appropriately designed, efforts at achieving better
social sector provision can be supported with infrastructure created with such
programmes. This would allow a given expenditure to realise more than one goal.
FISCAL
The
real challenge before the new government when dealing with the above issues is
that of breaking the barrier to increase public expenditure in the name of
meeting fiscal deficit targets implicitly set by the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) and the World Bank. To do so would require reversing the decline in the
tax-GDP ratio. It has been estimated that, if the ratio of central government
tax revenue to GDP which prevailed in 1990-91, prior to the onset of the current
reforms, were prevailing today, then the central government would have got an
additional amount in excess of Rs 30,000 crore per annum at current GDP. Since
India’s tax-GDP ratio is known to be lower than that of other similarly placed
countries, there is an obvious need to raise tax revenues through appropriate
measures of progressive taxation, including larger taxation of the service
sector, wealth taxation, especially taxation of financial assets, and so on.
Besides
taxation, expenditures can be increased by dropping the obsession with the
fiscal deficit, even when comfortable levels of foodstocks and foreign exchange
reserves are available and industrial capacity remains unutilised because of
lack of demand.
The
previous government, rather than exercising this option, sought to deal with the
fiscal crunch through the soft option of “mobilising” resources for the
budget with disinvestments. This must be stopped. Disinvestment of profit-making
public sector units (PSU) at throwaway prices is obviously irrational. But even
in some PSUs that are loss making their condition is explained by the level of
prices they charge rather than inefficiency.
Finally,
a truly socially beneficial growth strategy cannot be put in place without a
major role for the states. But state governments have for some time now been
trapped in a fiscal crunch, which has become unmanageable after the
implementation of the Fifth Pay Commission’s recommendations. An important
cause for the fiscal crisis faced by the state governments is the extremely high
interest rates on loan provided to them by the centre. By resorting to a
combination of debt write off and swaps of high interest debt for low interest
debt, the financial position of the states should be improved immediately.
These
are some of the measures that the new government must adopt, to respect Verdict
2004 and make Indian democracy meaningful.