People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVIII
No. 01 January 04, 2004 |
The
Nonsense Of GDP Growth
NEGATING
the empirical evidence and theoretical wisdom of the 1950s and 1960s, it has now
become fashionable to emphasise GDP growth. India’s Tenth Plan fixed the
target of 8 per cent per annum growth during 2002-07, while actual growth was
just 4.4 per cent in 2002-03. A US based management guru, C K Prahalad, has
recently marketed the possibility of 10-15 per cent per annum growth in coming
years. The mainstream economists in both India and abroad are busy with their
questionable econometric and statistical exercises to prove that this mythical
GDP growth rate is realisable if neo-liberal ‘reforms’ are pushed
vigorously, and that with the realisation of this high growth rate, the mass of
the people will automatically gain as jobs will be created and poverty will
vanish.
FALSIFYING
This,
however, is not true. In fact, present day GDP growth is jobless. Quite often,
instead of creating jobs, it results in job loss, which leads to accentuation of
poverty. In India, this all is happening ever since the rigorous pursuit of
neo-liberal ‘reforms’ began in the early 1990s. However, protagonists of
neo-liberal ‘reforms,’ engaged in the international financial institutions
funded research at so-called research organisations and other academic
institutions, are making frantic efforts to convince the people that India’s
GDP growth, accelerated by the neo-liberal ‘reforms,’ is egalitarian in the
sense that its gains have trickled down and have reached the common people.
This, in their opinion, is reflected in a “significant reduction” in the
incidence of poverty.
Thus
it seems that these so-called academics are determined to prove Josef Stiglitz
right who wrote in his book Globalisation
and Its Discontents, “The French intellectual Pierre Bourdieu has written
about the need for politicians to behave more like scholars and to engage in
scientific debate based on hard facts and evidence. Regrettably, the opposite
happens too often, when academics involved in making policy recommendations
become politicised and start to bend the evidence to fit the ideas of those in
charge.”
We,
however, totally reject this motivated research based on dubious statistical
methods and doubtful data. Nonetheless, we consider it necessary to explain why
high GDP growth is, even if it materialises, not sufficient for the well being
of the common people.
Modern
growth processes leave large segments of the population completely untouched.
Former World Bank president Robert McNamara had estimated that about 40 per cent
of the developing world’s population did not benefit at all from the economic
growth during the 1950s and 1960s. Even other studies of the 1960s did not
support the hypothesis that economic growth raises the share of income of the
poorest segments of the population. On the contrary, their results invariably
suggested that economic dynamism at low levels of development worked to the
relative disadvantage of lower income groups. Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft
Morris revealed in their study that the poorest 60 per cent group benefited only
when there were broad based efforts to improve the economy’s human resources.
Most empirical studies of that period suggest that in a developing country
obsession with economic growth is not correct. On the contrary, the policies of
the state in these countries should be oriented towards poverty alleviation,
employment generation, satisfying basic needs of the people and reduction in
income inequality.
INEGALITARIAN
Growth
was seen as an inegalitarian process by Marx. Several development economists
have also reached the conclusion that, given the institutional set-up of
non-socialist third world economies, one cannot conceive of any other form of
development except the enclave type which inevitably accentuates income
inequalities and incidence of poverty.
It
has been observed that incomes in the traditional sector show a tendency to
decline as a consequence of the development of the enclaves. In India, GDP
growth was 5.58 per cent per annum during 1991-2001. When we examine sectoral
rates, we find that agricultural growth rate was as low as 2.85 per cent per
annum, manufacturing growth was 4.01 per cent per annum and services sector grew
at 7.41 per cent per annum. Since poor households in India depend mostly on low
growth activities such as agriculture and industries for their subsistence, it
is no surprise that this 5.6 per cent per annum GDP growth has completely
bypassed them. Benefits of 7.4 per cent per annum growth in the services sector
have remained concentrated with the elite.
The
poor have suffered on account of enclave type economic growth due to one or more
of the following reasons.
The
developed enclave acquires power to exploit the traditional sectors. This
has actually happened in different parts of the country where people have
been driven off their land. Further, urban elites have turned the terms of
trade against the countryside.
Products
of the enclaves have been destroying traditional small-scale industries and
handicrafts. There are many more examples: household equipment has been
destroying domestic services and office machinery is destroying clerical
jobs, and the green revolution has ruined small and marginal farmers as they
cannot use bio-chemical inputs.
The
development of the enclave induces excessive migration from the rural
sector. Obviously, productive work does not exist for all of them in the
enclave. Therefore, many migrants from the rural sector fail to get jobs.
They swell the number of the unemployed and also contribute to urban slum
formation.
THE HOAX OF
As
far as the ‘trickle down effects’ of growth are concerned, they are not to
be taken seriously. By falsifying data, the neo-liberalisers try to convince
people that the benefits of high GDP growth ultimately reach all sections of the
society.
In
fact, nothing of the sort happens. Automatic trickle down is most unlikely
because in the upper class dominated society of India there is unequal access to
the opportunists of producing or obtaining the income from incremental GDP. It
is the richer groups which have access to all the opportunities and appropriate
the increased GDP, which leads to still sharper inequalities in income
distribution.
There
is no merit in income inequality, as the neo-liberalisers attribute to it.
Inequality of income distribution is not necessarily needed to promote savings
and investment. In fact, the doctrine that unequal distribution of income is
helpful to growth because only the rich save is a travesty of the truth. Even if
it is agreed that income inequality results in larger savings and investment,
leading to higher GDP growth, these developments may solidify production
structure in the direction of greater inequality. Once a production structure
conforming to the needs of unequal distribution and a domestic market reserved
for the elites have been developed, the process becomes irreversible. Therefore,
in India, given its high rate of population growth, increasingly capital
intensive technology, its limited resources and pursuit of neo-liberal economic
policies, trickle down is most unlikely in the normal context of purely GDP
growth.
IGNORING EMPLOYMENT
Widespread
unemployment exists in India along with appallingly low level of production.
India has been fighting hard for some time past on two fronts, viz, production
and employment, and in doing so has discovered that a success on production
front does not necessarily imply success on employment front also. For a
country, particularly if it is underdeveloped, the objectives of raising the
output level and employment generation are equally important. An ideal situation
for it would be that both production and employment increase simultaneously. But
often such a thing does not happen and a conflict develops between these two
objectives. In India, the policy makers are now aware of this conflict and they
accord overriding priority to GDP growth while employment generation receives
merely ritualistic support.
The
problem arsing from the incompatibility between the objectives of raising the
output levels and employment generation is really very serious and if India
earnestly wishes to overcome it, it has no choice except to discover labour-absorbing
techniques particularly suited to its requirements. Until India manages to do
that, it will have to make a difficult choice between the two more or less
equally important objectives. At present, the government’s obsession with
raising the GDP growth rate and its attempt to encourage workers’ retrenchment
in the private and public sectors shows its preference for growth. At a point of
time when employment elasticity has steeply fallen to 0.16, according to the
Planning Commission’s own admission, there is a strong case for according
overriding priority to employment. Obsession with GDP growth at this juncture is
both irrational and inegalitarian, as it is in conflict with elimination of
unemployment.
WHY PRIORITY TO EMPLOYMENT
Whenever
a conflict between growth and employment is unavoidable and optimisation of one
results in a setback to the other, employment is to be given priority over
output due to the following reasons.
First,
the life of unemployed persons in
India, particularly of these belonging to the lower strata of the society, is
very miserable. Keeping the pitiable condition of the unemployed in view, the
need for social security measures for them is felt in all egalitarian societies.
However, there is no social security arrangement for the unemployed in this
country. Unemployed persons in India either survive on the support which they
sometimes get from other members of the family or they fall back upon their
meagre savings. If nothing of the sort is possible, they borrow from various
sources at exorbitant rates of interest. Once fallen in a debt trap, they carry
the burden of debt for a long time, even after getting employment. Therefore,
employment generation in Indian conditions must receive overriding priority.
There
is a second reason why employment generation in this country deserves far
greater attention than it has received so far. Unemployment is a curse to a
person. It has an extremely demoralising effect on the unemployed. A person
loses self-respect if her or his unemployment is a prolonged one. It is to be
recognised that the preservation of self-respect is worth sacrificing some
production. In fact, of all the evils worklessness is the worst. Thus
unemployment is not to be seen as an evil merely because it results in a lower
national output but also because it causes frustration and moral degradation in
course of time, which ultimately vitiates the whole atmosphere of the society.
Thus it is worth losing some production for eliminating this evil.