People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVII
No. 42 October 19, 2003 |
Disinvestment For Whom?
C
P Chandrasekhar
THE
government, it appears, is desperate to abort the Supreme Court verdict staying
the disinvestment of oil majors Hindustan Petroleum Corporation Limited
(HPCL) and Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited (BPCL). On October 15, in
a completely different case relating to privatisation of Jessop & Co being
heard in the highest court, the attorney general pleaded for a “serious
reconsideration” of the judgment, on the grounds that its “potential
ramification and widespread consequences cast a cloud on the entire
disinvestments process”.
The
attorney general was both correct and wrong. The Supreme Court verdict of
September 16 did indeed have widespread ramifications. It stripped the executive
of its self-assumed autonomy in the areas of disinvestment and privatisation.
The court had in essence ruled that any enterprise created under or transferred
to public ownership by parliament cannot be privatised without parliamentary
approval. This, in itself, was a major ruling; given the fact that parliament
had been by-passed repeatedly in the course of the accelerated privatisation
programme adopted by the NDA government in recent times. But the judgment went
much further. It provided a definition of public ownership that cannot be
violated without parliamentary approval that has far-reaching implications. HPCL
and BPCL were units that were acquired in the early 1970s by Acts of parliament
that expressly stated that the activities in which they were involved
(especially the distribution and marketing of petroleum products) needed to be
brought under the aegis of the state. They must, therefore, vest with government
companies or units in which the government had a majority stake holding and
exercised managerial control.
LEGAL VIOLATION
The
proposed disinvestment of the two oil retail majors --- involving the sale of
34.01 per cent of equity in HPCL to a strategic partner who would be offered
managerial control and the sale through the market of 35 per cent of public
equity in BPCL --- violated both these requirements set by the parliamentary Act
acquiring them. The government’s equity stake would have fallen well below 51
per cent given the preexisting shareholding structure, and there would be an
explicit or implicit transfer of managerial control. Given that possibility,
their sale without parliamentary approval and revision of the Acts concerned was
an obvious legal violation.
But,
according to a reading of the judgment by the constitutional expert Rajeev
Dhavan, in the course of restraining the sale of HPCL and BPCL the two-judge
bench went further. It suggested that a process in which a company is set up by
the government as an “instrument of service”, even if not through a specific
Act, and explicitly provided grants through the government’s budget meets the
“technical requirement of parliamentary approval”. Therefore, in such cases
too, parliamentary approval for reducing the government’s stake or
transferring managerial control to the private sector should be required.
The highest court’s opinion is clear. If the parliament of
India had either explicitly or implicitly approved of a particular unit being
run as a government company, then the parliament’s approval is needed for
changing the status of the company and handing over control to the private
sector.
PARLIAMENTARY APPROVAL
Thus,
the HPCL/BPCL judgment completely deprives the government of the right to
by-pass parliament implicitly provided by earlier judgments. Those judgments had
accepted the view that disinvestment and/or ‘strategic sale’ (involving the
transfer of managerial control to an entity acquiring a minority block of
shares) were matters of public policy to be left to the executive to decide
upon. In fact, one immediate consequence, which had angered the disinvestment
minister Arun Shourie, is that the judgment challenged the validity of many, if
not all, acts of disinvestments and privatisation undertaken under the reform
strategy pursued since 1991.
In
this sense the attorney general’s statement before the court that the verdict
had major ramifications was right. But neither was his judgment that it had cast
a cloud over the disinvestment process nor was his tone of doom regarding the
consequent “danger to privatisation” warranted. The verdict does not ban
privatisation. It only requires parliamentary approval for the process and
introduces a needed corrective to the excessive power wielded by the executive
in the area. If the need for privatisation was accepted on the basis of
parliamentary approval, the government could go through with it.
Experience
indicates that absolving the executive of accountability to parliament has been
disastrous from the point of view of economic policy. Originally, privatisation
was seen as just one of many initiatives needed to restructure the public
sector, and was to be restricted to loss-making units that are best divested.
Over time, however, not only has privatisation been made the sole means of
public sector restructuring, but it has also been presented as the best option
in the case of virtually every profitable public unit.
IDEOLOGICAL THRUST
The
view that the government should not have been present in most areas it entered
has a two-fold ideological thrust. It presumes that the private sector should be
preeminent and the government should undertake an economic activity only when
the private sector for one reason or another is unwilling to enter. It also
assumes, contrary to the evidence provided by many a public enterprise, that
public sector units would by definition be inefficient. The latter assumption
allows losses suffered by public units for reasons completely unrelated to
efficiency to be attributed to inefficient functioning.
Even ignoring the fact that prejudices of this kind should never be
allowed to influence policy, this particular ideological frame should drive the
management of the public sector only if supported by a representative majority.
Clearly, the post-judgment “confession” by the government and the private
sector-controlled media that requiring parliamentary approval for privatisation
amounts to dumping the policy is indicative of the fact that nobody believes
that such a majority, let alone a consensus on the issue, exists.
Advocates
of reform who contend that there is now consensus around it are obviously not
willing to subject that view to a democratic test.
The reason for this is not hard to find. It emerges from the fact that the
process of sale of public assets has involved prices that have been unreasonably
low and would not have passed public scrutiny. In the controversies surrounding
the privatisation of units varying from Modern Foods to Balco, technical experts
have been at pains to point out that the price received by the government for
its equity was a fraction of that warranted by the value of the underlying
assets. Evidence on the prices of land, mining rights and assets like captive
power plants was provided to advance this case.
BREAKING PUBLIC SECTOR DOMINANCE
The
executive has at all times chosen to dismiss this view by referring to specious
arguments involving accounting principles, stock market prices and discounted
present values. Even when Centaur Hotel Mumbai, which the government had sold
for Rs 83 crore, was resold within four months by the original buyer for Rs 115
crore, the validity of the argument that either because of its desperation to
sell or for other reasons the government was undervaluing public assets was
dismissed.
To
top it all, the executive decision to resort to “strategic sales” (wherein
the purchase of a minority stake at basement bargain prices was adequate to
acquire managerial control) in order to attract buyers and make successful the
accelerated privatisation programme, was rendering the public sector a site for
primitive accumulation by private capital.
As the VSNL experience illustrated, such strategic sales can
provide the private buyer access to resources that made the investment more than
lucrative. In this case the Tata group, which purchased the strategic stake in
VSNL, tapped the cash reserves of the erstwhile public sector company to finance
the expansion of the private company, Tata Teleservices, a telecom start-up the
group controlled. That the
government is being driven by strong reasons other than economic rationality
even in the BPCL/HPPCL cases comes through from its initial responses to the
Supreme Court verdict.
Stating
that, “failure to act swiftly and decisively to counter the fallout of the
judgment would be viewed adversely,” the government seriously considered four
kinds of options: First, to issue an ordinance or enact appropriate legislation
empowering the government to disinvest equity in HPCL and BPCL or in any PSU,
and go ahead with the process of privatisation. Second, to reopen the issue by
seeking a presidential reference under Article 143 of the Constitution that
would be placed before a larger Bench. Third, to await any fresh case that may
come up as a result of this judgment or otherwise and that allows the government
to reopen the issue before a larger Bench and seek a reversal of the ruling.
Finally, pursue an option that emanates from an interpretation that the
judgment does not prohibit sale of companies that are not nationalised through
Acts of parliament. As part of this option, it was suggested that Indian Oil
Corporation, which was not constituted through an Act of parliament could be
split up, the non-saleable parts merged with HPCL and BPCL and the rest broken
into two, one of which is sold to a strategic partner and another to the public.
Since
there is no guarantee of success with the first two of these options which
requires either parliamentary support or a Supreme Court reversal, it is clear
that the government is veering round to relying on the latter two options.
Despite opposition from within the NDA government (especially the petroleum
minister), from the IOC union and officers and from the public, the IOC split is
still being considered. Meanwhile, the government has decided to use the case
relating to sick enterprise Jessop & Co
To influence the Supreme Court into changing a judgment which relates to
the successful oil majors HPCL and BPCL.
HELPING PRIVATE PRODUCERS
The
desperation to stay the course and the sudden attempt to bring IOC into the
disinvestment ambit indicates that the government in this case is being driven
by the desire to break public sector dominance over distribution of petroleum
products. IOC controls 52 per cent of the marketing network, and its sale can
realize this objective even if HPCL and BPCL, which together hold the rest,
cannot be privatised. Why this urgent desire to change the distribution scenario
through privatisation rather than new private entry, which is being permitted?
Raising that question, some commentators are seeing in the government’s moves
an effort to enhance the position of private petroleum producers, especially a
major like Reliance, which has no presence in distribution and would have to set
up full distribution network at considerable cost if it is to compete in that
market rather than distribute through the public sector. If this is true, the
aim of privatisation here is not to restructure the public sector but to favour
a private player, which already has a monopoly in some segments of the
petrochemical industry. If so, privatisation is once again being used as the
route to primitive accumulation by private capital in the country. This only
justifies the Supreme Court’s decision to curb the possibly misuse of its
power by the executive.