People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVII
No. 19 May 11, 2003 |
IT
is rare for the Reserve Bank of India to make very definitive and even partisan
statements about the broad contours of economic strategy. Central bank reports
are normally fairly staid documents, attempting to present balanced if boring
analyses of economic trends and policies. Over the past decade, as the other
official economic publications have tended to become more like publicity
handouts for the government rather than objective assessments of the state of
the economy, the RBI’s publications have been more circumspect.
All
that seems to be changing, along with so much else in economic institutions in
India. The latest RBI Currency and Finance Report (officially referring
to 2001-02 but published in April 2003) is for the first time organised around
the theme: no less than an assessment of the economic reforms programme of the
Government of India since 1991.
BIAS
AND GAPS
It
is a bold attempt, and certainly valuable given that it is coming from this
particular official quarter. The foreword (by RBI deputy governor
Rakesh Mohan) and the opening chapter (on the theme of the Report) give some
indication of the underlying bias that is operating: “The country has gained
significantly from policy reforms in the 1990s. Further gains are there for the
taking” (page I--3).
While
it may be unusual for an official document to wear its heart on its sleeve so
openly, it must be said that the subsequent chapters are much more carefully
worked and worded. The various chapters present surveys of literature and the
assessment of the team of writers, as well as a set of data pertaining to trends
in the real economy, fiscal and monetary policy, the financial sector and the
external sector.
Of
course, there are major gaps and limitations even in the presentation of the
broad trends. Thus, the entire Report contains no mention of employment
trends, as if employment is not and need not be a central concern of
macroeconomic policy. Similarly, the Report tends to accept uncritically the
disputed argument that there has been a dramatic decline in the incidence of
poverty, which is based on non-comparable consumption surveys conducted by the
NSSO. Nevertheless, there is much in the report that still provides an
interesting and useful account of the economy under neo-liberal reforms.
Much
of the trend analysis is conducted by comparing the pre-reform decade (here
defined as 1981-82 to 1990-91) and the post-reform period (1992-93 to 2002-03)
thereby excluding the “crisis year” 1991-92 from the calculations. These
data themselves tend to give the lie to the more optimistic assessment of the
reforms that is presented in the overview chapter of the Report, since they
reveal a number of weaknesses even in the aggregate growth patterns.
RETROGRESSION
IN
To
begin with, it is clear that very recent trends in the economy suggest that
economic activity has not only decelerated but is far below potential. This has
been led by the poor performance of agriculture and allied sectors, but
industrial growth also appears to be low over the recent period.
Indeed, only the services sector shows relatively high growth rates, and even
those have decelerated over the past three years.
This
is related to the deceleration in investment ratios. There has been a long run
tendency for savings and investment rates (as shares of GDP) to increase,
reflecting the usual pattern in industrialising economies. However, this
tendency appears to have come to a halt by the mid 1990s, and by the early years
of the current decade, the investment ratio had settled at between 23 and 24 per
cent. More disturbing, the savings rate actually exceeded the investment rate in
2001-02 (and most probably also in 2002-03, for which the NAS data is not yet
available).
This
is an indication of the extent of slack in the economy, the aggregate
unemployment and under-utilisation of capacity. There is no question that the
economy is operating well below potential, and the RBI also accepts this
diagnosis. However, the RBI’s own estimates of the potential income and the
output gap are not based on the full deployment of existing resources.
Rather, potential output is defined by some notion of “structural factors”
such as “the lack of appropriate (undefined) reforms in the agricultural
sector, infrastructure rigidities, labour market rigidities, weak bankruptcy and
exit procedures”, which suggest that it is also operating within narrow
conceptual confines of the liberalisers.
DIFFERENTIAL
PERFORMANCE
The
trend analysis of GDP confirms the picture of deceleration, especially over the
most recent period. The RBI has calculated semi-logarithmic trend rates of
growth for the relevant periods. While the trend growth rate of aggregate GDP
is estimated to have increased from 5.6 per cent over 1981-82 to 1990-91 to 6.1
per cent in the period 1992-93 to 2002-03, this masks very differential
performance across sectors. In fact, both the primary and secondary
sectors, as well as some important tertiary sectors have experienced
deceleration of growth along with much greater volatility of growth as expressed
in the coefficient of variation.
The
sharpest deceleration is of course to be observed for agriculture. It is worth
remembering that the primary sector’s long run trend rate of growth since
Independence has been 3 per cent, and the post-reform period marks the first
period when it has actually fallen well below that. Indeed, this low rate of
growth reflects the stagnation or even decline of agriculture in the more recent
period, as we will discuss below.
It
is true that this lower growth of agricultural GDP has been associated with
lower volatility as well, but that reflects the tendency to stagnation
especially in the latter part of the period. The Report provides insufficient
attention to the causes of this, and tends to underplay one of the more
important aspects that has affected value added in agriculture (as opposed to
gross production) – the impact of trade liberalisation in keeping many crop
prices down even when domestic output falls.
Manufacturing
is of course crucial to the Indian economy, and therefore it is disturbing to
see that the same tendencies are operative for this sub-sector as well.
Deceleration of output growth has been accompanied by increased fluctuations,
and it will become apparent that this is related to the even sharper slowdown in
manufacturing in the latter part of the period.
This
was accompanied by substantial slowdown and similar increase in volatility of
the infrastructure and utility sectors that are so important for manufacturing
growth as well --- electricity, gas and water supply.
It
is only the services sub-sectors that suggested any increase in rates of growth,
and that is primarily the reason why GDP growth in the aggregate has remained
respectable. Even here, however, financing, insurance, real estate and business
services registered a significant slowdown. Also, the acceleration in output
growth of community, social and personal services may not reflect a real
increase so much as an increase in public sector wages that occurred over this
period because of Pay Commission awards.
WHAT
EXPLAINS
What
explains this general deceleration in output growth most sectors? The RBI Report
suggests that this reflects the more significant slowdown that has occurred
after 1996. It is clear that agricultural deceleration was the most advanced,
with GDP growth in agriculture in the final five-year period averaging only 1
per cent per annum. But even manufacturing shows a very sharp slowdown, falling
in the last five years to only 4.2 per cent per annum - one of the lowest trend
rates of growth experienced for Indian manufacturing in any period since the
1950s.
The
stability of services growth over this period was clearly inadequate to counter
these recessionary trends, which is why the period 1997-98 to 2002-03 also shows
aggregate GDP growth at a lower rate of 5.3 per cent.
Over
this later period, savings rates also declined on average. This was
primarily due to the collapse of public sector savings, as the public sector
became a net dissaver. Indeed, savings was kept afloat essentially by the
household sector, since private corporate savings also declined as a share of
GDP over this period.
Investment
rates also declined on average after 1996.
Interestingly, the decline in investment reflected both public and private
sector investment deceleration, while the household sector actually increased
its investment (which is the same as its physical savings). This is but another
reflection of the increasing slack, or unemployment and under-utilisation of
resources, in the macro-economy, that has already been mentioned.
Public
sector investment was constrained by the falling tax-GDP ratios and the official
perception that fiscal deficits needed to be contained, which meant cutbacks on
public capital expenditure.
There is no surprise in the associated decline in private corporate investment
rates – the strong positive link between public and private investment in
India (and indeed in most developing countries) is by now well-established, and
the fact of recessionary tendencies in the economy during this period is also
widely accepted.
The
slowdown in manufacturing deserves closer attention. This was spread across a
very wide range of manufacturing sub-sectors. So much so, that only five
sub-sectors appear to have bucked the adverse trend: beverages and tobacco,
textile products, leather, chemicals and rubber, plastics petroleum and coal.
For most of traditional manufacturing, as well as for the range of capital goods
industries, the falls in growth rate, were actually quite steep.
The
RBI Report considers at some length the various hypotheses advanced to explain
the deceleration. It mentions the argument that has been advanced by Macroscan (The
Hindu-Business Line) earlier, that the slowdown reflected the satiation
of pent-up demand once the initial spurt of import-intensive production had
dealt with post-liberalisation consumer demand. Once that once-for-all increase
had been catered to, manufacturing faced a recession in the absence of any
further demand impetus, either form the domestic economy or through exports.
This was aided by the fact that the initial early 1990s expansion had not
greatly increased employment, and so had limited linkage and multiplier effects.
The
RBI appears to reject this argument, on the grounds that “the huge capacity
build up noticed in the first phase of reform runs counter to the monetary surge
in demand that was not likely to be sustained in the long run” (page III-30).
However, this counter-argument is weak at best, and actually contradicted by the
data provided in the very same Report, on capital goods production and import.
Both domestic production and imports of capital goods really increased together
in the middle of the 1990s, and peaked by 1997-98, when the onset of domestic
recession from 1996 finally dampened investor expectations. Since then, both
production and imports of capital goods have been relatively depressed,
indicating that investor expectations have yet to recover in the absence of any
stimulus either from the government or from the external sector.
In
addition, the Report argues that the fall in government investment does not per
se provide a satisfactory explanation of the slowdown, since government
productive expenditure also declines during the short-lived boom. But this is
precisely the point, which is that after that initial import-led consumption
boom was over, the slowdown in government investment made things worse because
there was no additional stimulus to private investment.
ILL-CONCEIVED
In
contrast, the other explanations that have been offered for the manufacturing
slowdown, which are apparently taken more seriously by the Report, are almost
laughable. The first relates to the “credit crunch” faced by the corporate
sector during 1995-96, when the RBI made large dollar sales to contain foreign
currency market volatility. This could hardly explain the continued depression
in investment until 2002-03. The important point about the credit market, which
is not made in the Report, is that the reduced access of small-scale
industry to formal credit after financial deregulation has dramatically weakened
its position and contributed substantially to the slowdown.
Similarly,
the Report argues that “the proportion of corporate funds locked up in
inventories and receivables went up steadily, leading to a scarcity of working
capital” (page III--30). This argument surely mistakes cause for effect ---
the increase in inventories is typically a sign of recession, not a factor
determining it.
The
Report also mentions the role of cyclical factors, such as the lagged effect of
low agricultural growth and the depressed international economic context. What
it fails to mention is that it is precisely in such circumstances that expansion
must come from government expenditure.
This
reflects the basic constraint within which the Report has been written, that it
is operating very much within the paradigm of marketist neo-liberal reform that
the policy makers in the finance and other ministries have adopted. In the
circumstances, it is hardly surprising that the Report is unable, despite its
apparent intentions, actually to offer an objective assessment of the Indian
reform experience.