People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVI No. 47 December 01,2002 |
Twelfth
Finance
Commission:
Ominous
Mandate
C
P
Chandrasekhar
EVEN
while
reducing
the
extent
of
devolution
of
funds
to
the
state
governments,
the
centre
is
attempting
to
use
statutory
and
non-statutory
transfers
to
the
states
as
levers
to
force
them
into
accepting
neo-liberal
reform
policies.
That
is,
a
major
component
of
the
so-called
“second
generation
reforms”
is
the
use
of
conditions
attached
to
constitutionally
required
transfers
as
a
means
to
force
state
government’s
to
accept
reforms
of
a
kind
required
to
appease
international
financial
capital
and
the
Bretton
Woods
institutions.
The
most
recent
example
of
this
tendency
is
the
terms
of
reference
provided
to
the
newly
constituted
Twelfth
Finance
Commission
(TFC),
which
is
to
be
headed
by
the
Andhra
Pradesh
Governor
and
former
governor
of
the
Reserve
Bank
of
India,
Dr
C
Rangarajan.
The
Commission
is
supposed
to
submit
its
final
report
by
July
2004
so
that
the
government
could
incorporate
the
recommendations
in
the
Budget
for
2005-06.
While
Dr
Rangarajan
is
the
chairman,
the
members
include
Planning
Commission
member
Som
Pal,
former
cabinet
secretary
T
R
Prasad
and
D
K
Srivastava
of
National
Institute
of
Public
Finance
and
Policy.
TERMS
OF
REFERENCE
As
has
been
the
case
with
most
economic
announcements
in
recent
times,
the
terms
of
reference
of
the
TFC
have
not
invited
much
comment,
even
though
they
reflect
a
further
widening
of
the
conventional
mandate
of
a
Finance
Commission
and
presage
a
process
in
which
state
governments
are
forced
to
go
along
with
the
neo-liberal
reform
agenda
of
the
central
government.
Speaking
to
the
press
soon
after
the
union
cabinet
cleared
the
terms
of
reference,
finance
secretary
S
Narayan
reportedly
said
that:
"As
compared
to
the
terms
of
reference
of
the
11th
Finance
Commission,
the
terms
of
the
12th
Commission
lays
emphasis
on
certain
efficiency
factors
such
as
adjustment
of
user
charges,
relinquishing
non-priority
enterprises
through
privatisation
or
disinvestment
and
resource
mobilisation
to
improve
the
tax-GDP
ratio."
This
can
only
be
taken
to
mean
that
a
state’s
access
to
resources
would
be
linked
to
its
willingness
to
raise
user
charges
for
the
public
services
it
provides,
disinvest
the
enterprises
it
owns
and
impose
new
taxes
to
raise
revenues
and
cover
more
of
its
expenditures.
Conventionally,
the
Finance
Commission
is
concerned
with
the
criteria
that
should
govern
distribution
of
taxes
between
the
centre
and
the
states
and
among
the
states
themselves.
The
evolving
mandate
of
Commissions
constituted
in
the
past
has
essentially
sought
to
address
two
issues.
First,
it
recognised
the
fact
that
in
a
federal
system,
the
ability
of
government
at
different
levels
to
raise
revenues
through
taxation
is
unlikely
to
match
the
responsibilities
shouldered
and
therefore
the
expenditures
undertaken
at
those
levels.
Hence
the
Finance
Commissions
were
mandated
with
determining
the
vertical
sharing
of
Union
taxes
between
the
centre
and
the
states.
Second,
in
order
to
reduce
the
large
inter-state
disparities,
which
would
widen
if
a
state’s
access
to
resources
was
determined
purely
by
its
GDP,
it
provided
for
the
construction
of
a
formula
that
would
prevent
poorer
states
from
being
trapped
in
their
underdevelopment
by
providing
a
weight
for
backwardness
in
the
determination
of
revenue
shares.
ROLE
OF
Despite
these
safeguards,
neither
have
the
states
been
able
to
obtain
adequate
resources
to
finance
their
expenditures,
nor
has
inter-state
disparity
been
reduced
substantially.
While
inadequate
resources
mobilisation
and
unnecessary
expenditures
at
the
state
level
have
contributed
to
the
financial
difficulties
confronted
by
the
state,
central
policies
have
played
a
major
role
in
generating
a
fiscal
crisis
at
the
state
level.
For
example,
it
has
been
observed
that
the
centre
has
over
time
sought
to
increase
the
share
of
non-sharable
revenue
sources
(such
as
special
surcharges)
in
its
total
revenues,
adversely
affecting
the
states.
Further,
neo-liberal
reform
has
affected
the
states
in
two
ways.
Stabilisation
policies
adopted
in
the
early
1990s
had
raised
domestic
interest
rates
substantially.
The
larger
outgo
on
account
of
interest
payments
meant
that
the
states
had
to
increase
the
volume
of
debt
incurred
by
them.
This
has
resulted
in
a
situation
where
today
the
restructuring
of
state-level
debt,
by
replacing
high-cost
with
low-cost
debt,
is
seen
as
an
important
means
to
resolve
the
fiscal
crisis
at
the
state
level.
In
addition,
direct
and
indirect
tax
concessions
provided
by
the
centre
as
part
of
neo-liberal
reform,
in
order
to
spur
private
initiative,
have
led
to
a
significant
decline
in
the
central
tax-GDP
ratio,
which
affects
the
states
adversely
as
well.
Not
surprisingly,
states
that
were
recording
revenue
surpluses
till
the
late
1980s,
witnessed
their
transformation
into
deficits
and
experienced
a
sharp
increase
in
those
deficits
through
the
1990s.
More
recently,
the
erosion
of
resources
available
to
the
states
has
led
up
to
a
crisis
because
of
the
implementation
of
the
Fifth
Pay
Commission’s
recommendations.
The
impact
of
those
recommendations,
which
states
were
forced
to
adopt
once
they
were
implemented
at
the
central
level,
was
that
the
ratio
of
salaries
and
wages
to
the
revenue
receipts
of
the
states,
which
had
been
going
down
till
1996-97,
rose
dramatically
and
almost
doubled
after
1997-98.
In
the
event,
the
gross
fiscal
deficit
of
states
which
was
below
3
per
cent
of
GDP
during
much
of
the
1990s
shot
up
to
5
per
cent
by
1999-2000.
With
this
growing
role
of
debt
in
financing
expenditures
the
outstanding
debt
of
all
state
governments,
more
than
doubled
from
Rs
243,000
crore
in
March
1997
to
about
Rs
500,000
crore
in
March
2001.
This
massive
increase
in
debt
had
as
its
corollary
a
more
than
six-fold
increase
in
the
interest
liability
of
all
states
over
the
1990s,
from
less
than
Rs
9,000
crore
to
more
than
Rs
54,000
crore.
Overall
the
states'
debt
to
GDP
ratio,
which
was
over
19
per
cent
in
the
early
1990s,
but
came
down
to
under
18
per
cent
by
1996-97,
rose
to
about
23
per
cent
in
the
four
years
ending
with
2000-01.
We
must
also
note
that
the
revenue
deficit,
or
the
excess
of
current
expenditures
over
revenues,
which
accounted
for
less
than
30
per
cent
of
the
gross
fiscal
deficit
of
the
states
in
the
early
1990s,
rose
to
60
per
cent
by
the
end
of
the
decade.
This
implies
that
nearly
two-thirds
of
the
debt
incurred
by
the
states
is
now
being
used
to
finance
current
expenditure.
As
mentioned
earlier,
in
an
ostensibly
cooperative
effort
between
the
centre
and
the
states
to
resolve
this
problem,
the
high-powered
committee
on
state
finances,
chaired
by
finance
minister
Jaswant
Singh,
is
mooting
a
debt-swap
mechanism,
involving
the
replacement
of
high
with
low
cost
debt,
as
a
solution.
This
together
with
the
move
to
replace
sales
tax
with
VAT
at
the
state
level
is
being
viewed
with
suspicion
by
the
states.
The
grounds
for
suspicion
are
strong,
given
the
evidence
that
the
centre
is
seeking
to
use
the
fiscal
problems
of
the
states,
which
have
been
partly
created
by
the
former,
to
force
the
latter
to
adopt
controversial
neo-liberal
policies.
In
the
past
this
was
being
done
through
means
other
than
conditions
attached
to
what
are
constitutionally
warranted
statutory
transfers
of
resources
to
the
states.
One
such
means
was
to
use
the
mechanism
of
non-statutory
transfers
to
the
states,
principally
through
the
Planning
Commission,
to
force
unpopular
policies
on
the
states.
The
other
was
to
encourage
state
governments
to
approach
agencies
like
the
Asian
Development
Bank
and
the
World
Bank
for
project
funding,
in
return
for
which
they
demand
a
restructuring
of
finances
by
the
states.
This
was
what
has
happened
in
cases
like
Orissa
and
Andhra
Pradesh
and
is
currently
underway
in
Kerala.
It
also
was
a
reason
for
controversy
in
the
state
of
West
Bengal.
FORCING
NEO-
But
starting
with
the
Eleventh
Finance
Commission,
the
effort
to
force
the
states
into
accepting
neo-liberal
reform
policies
has
involved
making
suitable
additions
to
the
original
mandate
for
such
Commissions
laid
down
in
the
constitution.
Thus,
the
Presidential
Order
of
April
28,
2000,
had
asked
the
11th
Finance
Commission
``to
draw
a
monitorable
fiscal
reforms
programme
aimed
at
reduction
of
revenue
deficit
of
the
states
and
recommend
the
manner
in
which
the
grants
to
states
to
cover
the
assessed
deficit
on
their
non-Plan
revenue
account
may
be
linked
to
progress
in
implementing
the
programme.''
Thus
the
11th
Commission
was
asked
to
include
the
formulation
of
a
fiscal
reform
programme
in
its
terms
of
reference.
By
doing
so
the
centre
was
not
merely
seeking
to
give
a
particular
kind
of
“fiscal
reform”
constitutional
validity,
but
asking
the
commission
to
give
the
centre
the
right
to
use
provision
of
assistance
to
cover
non-Plan
revenue
deficits
as
an
instrument
to
enforce
compliance
with
such
a
reform
programme.
Not
surprisingly,
many
states,
led
by
Kerala
had
expressed
strong
reservations
about
the
additional
terms
of
reference.
Now
the
centre
has
gone
even
further.
To
start
with,
the
TFC
has
once
again
been
asked
to
suggest
a
plan
to
restructure
public
finances
to
restore
budgetary
balance
and
macro
economic
stability
and
reduce
the
debt
burden.
In
addition,
as
stated
earlier
it
has
been
required
to
provide
weightage
to
a
state’s
willingness
to
implement
“reform”
policies
such
as
raising
user
charges,
privatise
and
reduce
the
tax-GDP
ratio
when
determining
its
access
to
a
constitutionally
guaranteed
share
in
resources.
Further,
to
ensure
that
this
effort
at
strapping
the
states
into
the
reform
process
would
be
successful,
this
time
around
the
government
has
decided
to
give
the
Planning
Commission
a
role
in
influencing
the
devolution
formula
and
the
conditionalities
to
be
associated
with
the
provision
of
a
share
to
the
states
in
central
resources.
Clearly,
Planning
Commission
member
Som
Pal
is
an
“ex-officio”
nominee
to
the
Finance
Commission,
and
is
likely
to
ensure
this
role
for
the
body
which
hitherto
could
only
use
non-statutory
transfers
as
a
means
of
pushing
the
central
agenda
at
the
state
level.
This
attempt
to
use
the
Finance
Commission
to
push
through
what
is
the
real
thrust
of
the
so-called
“second-generation”
of
reforms,
namely,
the
enforced
adoption
of
reform
polices
in
a
host
of
areas
which
fall
within
the
jurisdiction
of
the
states
and
not
the
centre,
is
clearly
a
violation
of
the
constitutional
mandate
in
this
regard.
Article
280
Clause
(1)
of
the
Constitution
of
India
provides
for
a
statutory
Finance
Commission,
being
set
up
every
five
years,
to
recommend
the
rules
that
should
govern
the
devolution
of
funds
from
centre
to
the
states
and
their
distribution
among
the
states.
The
choice
of
a
five
year
life-span
for
the
recommendations
of
any
single
Commission
implies
that
those
who
framed
the
Constitution
wanted
changes
in
the
economic
structure
that
occur
with
development
to
be
taken
account
of
when
formulating
devolution
rules.
However,
using
the
Finance
Commission,
which
is
a
constitutional
instrument,
as
an
agency
to
push
through
a
highly
controversial
change
in
the
economic
policy
regime
is
clearly
a
breach
of
its
constitutional
obligation
by
the
centre.
Using
the
Planning
Commission,
which
is
an
administrative
body,
to
implement
this
subversion
of
the
work
of
a
constitutional
institution
such
as
the
Finance
Commission
is
an
even
greater
violation.
It
is
imperative
that
the
states
challenge
the
centre’s
manoeuvres
in
this
regard,
so
as
to
protect
the
freedom
provided
by
the
Constitution
to
frame
their
own
policies
in
areas
identified
as
being
within
their
jurisdiction.